Copyright © 2013 by the author(s). Published here under license by The Resilience Alliance.
Go to the
pdf version of this article
The following is the established format for referencing this article:
Duer-Balkind, M., K. R. Jacobs, B. Güneralp, and X. Basurto. 2013. Resilience, social-ecological rules, and environmental variability in a two-species artisanal fishery. Ecology and Society 18(4): 50.
http://dx.doi.org/10.5751/ES-05751-180450
ResearchResilience, Social-Ecological Rules, and Environmental Variability in a Two-Species Artisanal Fishery
1Department of the Environment, Washington, DC, 2School of Forestry and Environmental Studies, Yale University, New Haven, CT, USA, 3NOAA Coastal Management Fellow at the Puerto Rico Coastal Zone Management Program, San Juan, PR, 4Department of Geography, Texas A&M University, College Station, TX, USA, 5Duke Marine Lab, Nicholas School of the Environment, Duke University, Beaufort, NC, USA
ABSTRACT
Social-ecological resilience is an increasingly central paradigm for understanding sustainable resource management. In this study, we aimed to better understand the effect of environmental variability on the resilience of fishery systems, and the important role that social institutions and biophysical constraints play. To explore these issues, we built a dynamic model of the pen shell fishery of the indigenous Seri people in the Gulf of California, Mexico. This model included the dynamics of the two dominant species in the fishery (Atrina tuberculosa and Pinna rugosa), several institutional rules that the Seri use, and a number of ecological constraints, including key stochastic variables derived from empirical data. We found that modeling with multiple species, rather than the standard one-species model, uncovered more of the resilience that is present in the system. We also found that it is the combination of several social-ecological rules working in conjunction with the endogenous environmental variability that helps ensure the resilience of the system.
Key words: artisanal fisheries; common-pool resources; environmental variability; Gulf of California, Mexico; multi-species; resilience; social-ecological systems; stochasticity; system dynamics
INTRODUCTION
Sustaining small-scale fisheries is of vital importance to the livelihood of many fishing communities across the world (Berkes et al. 2001, Béné 2006). How to achieve this, however, is unresolved because most of what we know about fisheries comes from industrialized country’s experiences, which often do not apply to small-scale fishing settings in developing countries (Pauly 2006). One of the more striking differences is the multi-species character of artisanal fisheries; artisanal fishers are apt at switching harvested species depending on a suite of social-ecological conditions, an adaptive strategy that is linked to the apparent resilience of artisanal fisheries (Cinner et al. 2012). Also, the compliance to regulations suited to the specific socioeconomic and ecological contexts of each fishery is important (McClanahan et al. 2011).
Resilience is the amount of disturbance or change a system can sustain without shifting from one system state to another (Walker et al. 2004). The concept is non-normative; therefore, the shift may be to a more or less desirable state, however defined. When studying the resilience of social-ecological systems (SESs), it is often not only the resilience of the natural resource stocks that is in question but also that of the institutions that govern these resources (Cashore and Howlett 2007, Young 2010). Other resilience studies of marine coastal resources have explored sustainable small-scale fisheries as related to path dependence and transformation in governance (Gelcich et al. 2010), co-management and attributes of success (Gutiérrez et al. 2011), and mismatches between industrial fishery management and the biological and socioeconomic context of invertebrate artisanal fisheries (Freire and García-Allut 2000, Defeo and Castilla 2005).
Previous works have observed that a system may be forced over a threshold into an alternate state that may be reached simply by the slow degradation of the system (Scheffer et al. 2001, Güneralp and Barlas 2003). Detecting the gradual erosion of resilience is critical to assessing the vulnerability of a community or ecosystem to variability in the environment (Scheffer et al. 2001), but detection can be challenging and requires systematic investigation of the interactions among its various components. Moreover, while shocks and stressors are critical to pushing a system close to a threshold, it may often be natural stochastic variations that push it over the edge. Environmental variability is ubiquitous in the natural world and can play a critical role in the dynamics of SESs (Ludwig et al. 1993). Stochasticity becomes central, then, to our understanding of when and why shifts in system states occur (Beisner et al. 2003).
The area around the Infiernillo Channel, between the Sonora mainland and Tiburon Island on the Gulf of California, Mexico, is a protected homeland area for the Seri people, or Comcáac people (Fig. 1). In their artisanal fishery, the Seri harvest pen shells, or Callos de Hacha, large sessile bivalve mollusks that live buried in the sand on the seafloor (Moreno et al. 2005). Over the years, the Infiernillo Channel has remained home to the most abundant pen shell beds in the region, while the neighboring Mexican fishery of Kino Viejo just south of the channel has been dramatically depleted (Basurto et al. 2012). Extensive fieldwork and case studies have indicated that the local institutions that the Seri have created to govern their common pool resources play a key role in their success (Basurto 2005, 2006).
Bueno and Basurto (2009) developed a deterministic dynamic model to study the resilience of the pen shell fishery of the Seri. Their study demonstrated the role of very small, incremental endogenous changes in the relationship between ecological and socio-cultural variables in facilitating the collapse of a seemingly resilient system. We explore several major elements of the system that have not been previously examined, including its two-species character, using an expanded model. The model incorporates both stochastic elements and several social-ecological rules; we study how their dynamic interactions affect the resilience of the system. The social-ecological rules are the institutional rules and ecological constraints that collectively govern harvesting patterns in the fishery. Our objective is to systematically analyze the potential role of (1) interactions between institutional rules and biophysical settings, and (2) dynamic environmental variability on the resilience of an SES, using an experimental design framework.
Our study has two main hypotheses. First is that including both species in the model will more accurately capture the inherent resilience of the system—as Seri fishers shift their harvest between the two species according to their social-ecological rules. Second is that incorporating environmental variability into the model will increase the range of possible outcomes and degrade the system’s resilience, on average, as the increased variability will increase the system’s chances of crossing over a threshold into collapse. We conducted a series of simulation experiments to test these hypotheses, each with different combinations of stochastic variables, institutional rules, and biophysical constraints. Our results, which affirm our first hypothesis but refute the second, can inform studies on management of two-species artisanal fisheries.
METHODS
Building a dynamic model of the Seri social-ecological system
The Seri fishery includes two major species—
Atrina tuberculosa (
At) and
Pinna rugosa (
Pr) (Basurto 2006).
At is smaller and sells for a much higher price because it is only sold fresh, while
Pr is often sold frozen. Incorporating the immature and mature population dynamics of both species and Seri institutional rules provided a richer and more complete representation of the system structure in relation to its resilience properties than would a more conventional single-species model (Shelton and Mangel 2011). A causal loop diagram presents the major feedback structures of the modeled system (Fig. 2). The time horizon of the simulations was 100 years; the time step was one week (0.02 years), small enough to capture the finer grain of decision-making by the fishers as well as the population dynamics of the species (Ford 1999). The model was built using the Vensim software, produced by Ventana Systems, Inc. The parameter values and assumptions in the model were based on data and information collected from the field over the past decade by X. Basurto, and from peer-reviewed literature (Appendix 1). The full list of equations and a copy of the model are provided in Appendices 2 and 3, respectively.
Population growth, driven by two positive, or reinforcing, feedback loops (R1a and R1b), is moderated by two negative, or balancing, feedback loops (B2a and B2b), where an increase in population causes a shrinking of the resources available to the species, which results in fewer young pen shells surviving, and thus a slowing of the population growth (Fig. 2). The carrying capacity of each species was estimated by extrapolating the total number of pen shells found in one sample area to the total area and applying the average 2:1 ratio of
Pr to
At (based on field data collected by X. Basurto for three time periods: 2000–2001, 2004–2006, and 2009–2012). This nonetheless remained a first-order approximation because there were not sufficient data on habitat and physiological characteristics of the two species to produce more reliable estimates (Pineda 2000). The survival function for newly recruited individuals was a smooth curve based on the Beverton-Holt equation used to model fish populations, wherein recruitment was based primarily on the population of mature, reproducing individuals (Ricker 1975) (Fig. 3A).
Seri social-ecological rules
The Seri rely on several institutional rules in managing their fishery; in addition, the fishery is subject to certain ecological constraints imposed by its biophysical setting. We labeled these rules and constraints, which collectively govern harvesting patterns in the fishery, as social-ecological rules. We present the social-ecological rules as they are explicitly represented in the model. Social-ecological rules are not a representation of how the Seri think of institutional constraints they design and articulate to outsiders. Rather, these rules represent the authors’ translation and interpretation of how key institutional and ecological constraints may affect the dynamics of the social-ecological system in question:
- a rule governing the number of days spent harvesting pen shells each year;
- a set of rules governing areas that are off-limits;
- a rule governing the allocation of harvest effort between the two species;
- a set of rules governing the harvest of immature individuals;
- a set of rules governing outsider fishing boats in the territory and how those outsiders operate while in the fishery.
Rule 1 was set to 50%, or half the days of the year (it could be increased or decreased to compensate for environmental shocks, as was examined in Bueno and Basurto 2009). Rule 2 represents the rules that render certain areas off-limits for commercial harvesting, and includes both ecological constraints, such as seagrass beds, which are difficult and hazardous areas in which to gather pen shells, and social rules that reserve sandbars for subsistence fishing, mainly by women, elders, children, and adults without access to diving gear. When eelgrass (
Zostera marina) is present in the channel, the pen shell beds are covered and therefore out of reach for harvesting (Basurto 2008). The limits on harvesting within seagrass beds were implemented in the model through a mechanism that reduces the harvest by a percentage equal to that of the area covered by eelgrass during the eight months of each year. The limits on harvesting from sandbars were implemented by considering the sandbars to be permanently outside the spatial coverage of the model (Bueno and Basurto 2009).
Rule 3 involves the balancing feedback loops B3a, B3b, B4a, and B4b in Fig. 2. Seri fishers report that they can, and do, distinguish between the two species on the seafloor and allocate their harvesting effort between the two according to their relative abundance. While we hypothesized that this method helps keep both populations from collapsing, we do not assert that the Seri do this out of altruism or long-term decision-making. There is a higher financial gain per unit effort for harvesting
At.
At can only be sold fresh, and thus commands a much higher price than
Pr, which is often sold frozen. Seri fishers would thus preferentially target
At for harvesting if it is sufficiently abundant. When
At is much less abundant, fishers either target the two species equally or even preferentially harvest
Pr because it is more beneficial to harvest
Pr rather than seek scarce
At. We represented this strategy as a functional form similar to Holling’s Type III functional response curve. Our formulation of this rule was similar to other optimal foraging theory (OFT) models that assume a forager aims to maximize short-term gains, whether in energy (for animals and subsistence hunters/fishers) or revenue (for commercial artisanal fishers) (Stephens and Krebs 1986, Aswani 1998). Because fishers switch between only two species, the same OFT curve drives harvesting effort for both species (Fig. 3B). As relevant data become available, additional factors could be incorporated into this formulation, such as monetary units, or net effort expended in terms of kilocalories (Aswani 1998, Béné and Tewfik 2001).
Unlike some artisanal fisheries, the Seri do not have explicit rules that forbid the harvesting of immature individuals; nonetheless, empirical data indicate that immature individuals generally make up less than 30% of the catch. Rule 4 represents the combination of factors that keep immature harvests at this level or below, including both the Seri preference for harvesting, and ease of locating, larger individuals of either species. Due to its slower growth rate, we hypothesized that
Pr would be less resilient in our model, absent of countervailing forces. So, as a scenario analysis, we also studied the effect on the system of modifying Rule 4 to specifically ban harvesting of any immature
Pr.
The Seri regulate how many outsider boats are allowed in their territory (Rule 5). A Seri fisherman must ride on each outsider boat to ensure it follows the community’s rules. The Seri fisherman actively participates in the harvest and reaps a share of the catch, which is customarily determined to be equally distributed among all crew members and the boat owner. The increase in number of boats is one of the main stressors on the fishery, and it is to this increase in harvest pressure that we tested the resilience of our modeled system. Experiments wherein institutional rules 3 and 4 were “turned off” represented cases in which all the new boats were outsiders’ boats.
Incorporating stochasticity into the dynamic model
Three key parameters in the model were given stochastic analogues to represent either environmental variability—in the case of variables “lifespan of
At” and “lifespan of
Pr”—or variability that relates to drivers of environmental forcing and the social subsystem, in the case of variable “fishing luck.” Thus, in our study, environmental variability refers to dynamic demographic variation in recruitment, death, and harvest rates in response to weather, disease, competition, predation, or other factors not captured by the model. The stochasticity dealt with in this model was in some ways different from the stochasticity often studied in resilience science. Usually, stochasticity is used to refer to shocks coming from outside the system, which represents exogenous and hard-to-predict risks. The mature lifetime variables, on the other hand, are endogenous to the system. In the real world, environmental variability is highly correlated over time (e.g., while a very hot day can be followed by a very cold day, it is more likely to be followed by another hot day). Thus, we modeled all three stochastic variables so that the successive values of a variable over time were, while following a random pattern, partly conditioned on the values of that variable in the preceding time points. It is as if the random variability in these variables had inertia, or memory, in which the next value was not independent of the last, as in a traditional random normal Gaussian distribution, but depended on history (Sterman 2000: 917). This type of random process is called pink noise or 1/f noise (Halley 1996).
The literature suggests that
At and
Pr, which differ greatly in size, may also differ in lifespan (Baqueiro and Castagna 1988).
At and related species grow rapidly and reach sexual maturation at 1 year of age (Bueno and Basurto 2009). The genus
Atrina reaches sexual maturity at ~10 cm in shell length (Ahumada-Sempoal et al. 2002), which suggests that the
At harvested in the channel had a chance to reproduce at least once before harvesting, as most of them (70.2%,
n = 3261) measured at least twice the minimum size for sexual maturity (average size = 20.8 cm, SD = 2.53) (based on field data collected by this study for three time periods: 2000–2001, 2004–2006, and 2009–2012). Literature on the lifespan of species similar to
P. rugosa, e.g.,
Spondylus calcifer and
Pinna nobilis, suggests that they can reach an age ranging from 12 to 20 years and take 2.5 to 4 years to mature (Vicente et al. 1980, Siletic and Peharda 2003, Cudney-Bueno and Rowell 2008). Thus, in the model, mature lifespans of
At and
Pr were normally distributed with a mean of, respectively, 9 years (SD = 2) and 12 years (SD = 3) and time to mature of 1 year and 2 years, respectively, to capture the differences between the species. Because a new cohort of individuals is born each year, the correlation time for both species was set as 1 year.
Fishing luck captures influences on harvest success such as weather conditions, malfunctioning equipment, skill and experience of the crew, or turbidity of the water affecting the divers’ harvesting efficiency. Fishing teams tend to choose minimum-risk strategies depending on environmental conditions such as seasonal weather, but that does not guarantee every fishing outing will be a success. We assumed that fishing luck was normally distributed (mean = 1, SD = 0.4) based on the recorded daily variation in harvests collected by X. Basurto and colleagues in 2000, 2001, and 2009. While many factors influence fishing luck, seasonal weather patterns are crucial and more likely to be correlated over time than are some of the other drivers of fishing luck; therefore, the correlation interval of the random variability in fishing luck was 0.25 years.
Validation testing
Prior to conducting our experiments, we built confidence in the model by using several validation tests to ensure an adequate representation of the SES for the purposes of our study. The validation process was a gradual one, dispersed throughout the methodology, beginning with model conceptualization and continuing through experimentation (Barlas 1996). Our model was not expected to provide “point” predictions but rather to capture the broad dynamic patterns of the system (behavioral validation) for the correct reasons (structural validation). Therefore, the structural validity of the model was as important as its behavioral validity. We divided the formal validation work into two phases, following an established procedure in systems modeling (Barlas 1996). In structural validation tests, we assessed the logical validity of model equations by evaluating them individually and by testing their behavior under extreme conditions. With behavior validation tests, we evaluated the patterns of key variables generated by the model against the available data. The comparison between model-generated values and observed values allowed us to evaluate if the model was an adequate representation of the real-world system. The results of some of these comparisons are discussed in the
Results section.
Across many disciplines, it has become recognized that expert knowledge is an important and critical component of dynamic-modeling studies (Balci 1994, Lutz and Samir 2010). Therefore, in addition to these empirical tests, one of the co-authors (X. Basurto) contributed his expert knowledge on the Seri fishery extensively during the model building and validation processes.
Hypotheses testing
To test our hypotheses, we compared model runs with deterministic and stochastic lifetime and “fishing luck” variables, and with and without social-ecological rules governing relative foraging effort (Rule 3) and the harvest of immature individuals (Rule 4), for a total of 16 scenarios. The base case was fully deterministic and assumed there were no social-ecological rules in force that distinguished between the two species. In half the scenarios, lifetime was made deterministic by setting
At lifetime’s mean value of 9 years as constant, and
Pr lifetime’s mean value of 12 as constant, and in the other half of the scenarios, lifetime was a stochastic function, as previously described. Fishing luck could be either a stochastic function or an identity function of 1. Rule 3 was active when the fishers varied harvest effort between
At and
Pr according to the OFT function from Figure 3B, or was “off” when the relative abundance of the species was not considered. The eight experiments where Rule 4 was active constituted a scenario test where fishers did not harvest immature
Pr. Each experiment consisted of 10 replications to better capture the breadth of random variability. For each of the 16 experiment scenarios, we conducted two tests—one to test resilience to collapse, and one to test the system’s ability to recover from a near-collapsed state (referred to as the “collapse experiments” and the “recovery experiments,” respectively).
To test the system’s resilience to collapse, we let the system operate with 15 boats, then increased the number of boats at Year 5 and kept it constant for the remaining 95 years (the starting point of 15 boats was consistent with the field data collected by this study during 2000–2001, 2004–2006, and 2009–2012). We ran a multivariate sensitivity analysis for each experiment with 10 replications, and varied the number of additional boats between 0 and 50 to represent the change in fishing pressure. Collapse was defined as the overall pen shell population falling below 10% of carrying capacity in more than 2/3 of the runs for that level of fishing pressure. In order to capture the range of variability, we also recorded the “range” for each collapse experiment—the difference between the number of boats required to cause the overall pen shell population to fall below 10% of carrying capacity in at least one replication and the number of boats required to cause the overall pen shell population to fall below 10% of carrying capacity in each of the 10 runs.
To look at the system’s ability to bounce back, we ran a second set of experiments. In each experiment, we increased the number of boats in Year 5 from 15 to a number sufficient to engender eventual collapse, and then 30 years later, we brought the fishing effort back down to 15 boats—representing a scenario in which, for instance, the Seri decide to no longer allow outside fishers into their channel. Because of the wide variation in the critical level of fishing effort across the experiments, one single elevated fishing effort level could not be chosen to engender collapse in all the experiments. To compare like items, we separated the 16 experiments into four groups depending on which social-ecological rules were active or not, and identified the average threshold level, and then ran all four recovery experiments for that set with the same number of boats. Recovery was defined as the first stretch of more than 5 years where the total pen shell population equaled or exceeded the level it was at prior to the increase in fishing pressure in Year 5. As with the collapse experiments, each experiment consisted of 10 replications.
RESULTS
Prior to running any experiments, we compared model results with real-world data for validation purposes. The most detailed observed data were from daily harvests of the two species (by weight). Data collected by X. Basurto in 2000, 2001, and 2009 suggested that the daily harvest of an individual Seri boat crew is, on average, 27 kg of
Pr and 7 kg of
At, that there are, on average, 15 Seri boat crews harvesting on any given day, and that crews harvest, on average, 50% of the days in each year. Extrapolating daily harvests into a yearly harvest, with the average fleet of 15 boats fishing 50% of the year, yielded an average (median) yearly harvest of 82 tons of
Pr and 14 tons of
At. Our model predicted that a fleet of 15 boats operating in conditions similar to experiment #8 would harvest, on average (median), about 82 tons of
Pr and 13 tons of
At each year. Experiment #8, with both stochastic rules and the OFT effort switching rule but with no limitation on harvesting of immature pen shells, most closely resembled the real-world conditions of the Seri fishery during the time period for the observed data. The 75th and 25th percentiles and maximum and minimum (nonoutlier) values of the extrapolated observed harvest yield were also very similar to the model results. The observed and modeled probability distributions are shown in Fig. 4.
In the first set of experiments on the collapse threshold, there appeared to be four distinct cohorts of experiments, depending on which social-ecological rules were in place (Table 1). In the base-case scenario (experiment #1), it took 23 boats to overharvest the system to the point of collapse; this did not change with the addition of either one of the stochastic rules (experiments #2 and #3), and with both stochastic rules active, a collapse threshold of 24 boats resulted (experiment #4). As expected, the system was most resilient with all social-ecological rules in place. With both rules in place (experiments #13–#16), it took 50–52 boats to collapse the fishery; with only Rule 3 in place (experiments #5–#8), it took 40–42 boats; and with only Rule 4 in place (experiments #9–#12), it took 26–27 boats. Several sample runs illustrating collapse scenarios in different experiments are shown in Fig. 5A.
The recovery experiments likewise sorted into the four cohorts based on the institutional rules (Table 2). With both institutional rules active, the system recovered in 5.6–13 years (average recovery of 10.3–12.4 years). When the fishers took into account the relative abundance of the species (Rule 3), but did not limit the harvest of immature
Pr, the system recovered in 18.2–29.0 years (average recovery of 19.2–22.6 years). With only a rule to limit harvesting of immature
Pr active, the system recovered in 20.3–61.5 years (average recovery of 27.2–53.2 years). Five different experiment runs are displayed in Figure 5B.
Something very different happened in experiments #1–#4, when neither institutional rule was in force. Without either rule to lower the relative fishing pressure on
Pr, the
Pr population, as a result of its longer maturation times, was not sufficiently resilient to recover from the near-collapsed state it reached by year 30, and only the
At population recovered. However, because
At was limited by its own carrying capacity, lower than that of
Pr, the total pen shell population never climbed to the level it was at prior to the increase in fishing pressure (Fig. 5B). Therefore, we recorded results of N/A for recovery experiments #1–#4. Either institutional rule was sufficient to keep
Pr from collapsing (Fig. 5C).
The stochastic variables did make a small difference in the range of collapse thresholds (Table 3). Because higher collapse thresholds had larger numerical ranges, the range was best measured as a percentage of the average number of boats needed to cause collapse. Again, there were four distinct cohorts. By including stochastic fishing luck while keeping average lifespan deterministic (experiments #3, #7, #11, #15), results ranged 2–6%. When stochastic lifespans were included for both species without any variation for fishing luck (experiments #2, #6, #10, #14), results ranged 4–17%. When both stochastic variables were included (experiments #4, #8, #12, #16), results ranged 7–8%.
The effect of stochasticity was best shown by the range of recovery times for each of the recovery experiments, measured as a percentage of the average recovery time (Table 4). The results were clearly grouped by stochastic rules. Experiments with both stochastic factors had recovery periods that ranged 90–96%; experiments with stochasticity only in lifetime had recovery periods that varied by 7–88%; and experiments with stochasticity only in fishing luck had recovery periods that varied by 23–69%.
DISCUSSION
It is important to be specific about what exactly is being examined (“resilience of what”) and against what specific impacts that system’s resilience is measured (“resilience to what”) (Scheffer et al. 2001). We expressly looked at the Seri community’s social-ecological rules as factors that help maintain or degrade resilience; thus, it is the resilience of the Seri pen shell fishery to overfishing that is the subject of this paper. By drawing a larger system boundary around the system, we treated the fishing pressure as an endogenous attribute of the system rather than an exogenous factor of the sort more commonly studied in resilience research (Guttal and Jayaprakash 2007).
Our first hypothesis was that disaggregating the system into two species and incorporating social-ecological rules the Seri use to shift their harvest between the two species would better capture the resilience of the actual system. Our results affirm this hypothesis. By shifting fishing pressure from one species to another, the Seri maintain the fishery longer with more fishers and larger harvests. Compared to the scenarios wherein fishing pressure was applied regardless of species, the experiments where social-ecological rules limited harvesting of immature
Pr (Rule 4) were, on average, able to withstand three more boats before collapsing, or 12% more than the 23–24 boat baseline; experiments with fishing effort that varied between the two species according to the foraging response curve (Rule 3) were able to withstand an average of 17 extra boats before collapse (75% increase); and experiments with both rules were able to withstand 27–29 extra boats (~120% increase). Furthermore, comparing all runs with social-ecological rules to their counterparts, we found that adding the rules decreased the number of years it takes the system to recover from near-collapse, to as little as 5–13 years.
The results also show the importance of different management strategies for different species. In our model,
Pr’s longer maturation time and larger immature harvest made it more susceptible than
At to fishing pressure. In the absence of any management strategy to correct for it, the population of
Pr is susceptible to an early collapse. However, by either limiting their harvest of immature
Pr directly (Rule 4) or shifting their relative fishing effort (Rule 3), the Seri can give immature
Pr a greater chance of growing to maturity. More importantly, our results show that a carpet ban on immature harvesting, as was modeled in our scenario test with Rule 4, is not needed to prevent either species’ collapse, so long as the fishers pay attention to the relative proportion of the two species, and adjust accordingly. Indeed, paying attention to the relative abundance of the two species is a much more effective strategy than a targeted ban on immature harvests. More field studies of
Pr and
At would be needed to verify that
Pr is actually less resilient than
At in their natural habitat in the absence of Seri rules.
Our second hypothesis was that introducing environmental variability would increase the range of possible outcomes but might also reduce the resilience of the system, on average, by making it more likely that a critical threshold would be crossed. Our findings show that stochasticity does result in an increased range of possible outcomes. The findings also show that stochasticity can marginally increase the resilience of the system. Contrary to our original hypothesis, the experiments show that the stochasticity in the mature lifespan actually increases the resilience of the system, as measured by the amount of fishing pressure it can sustain, but only by one to three additional boats before collapse (only 3–6%), as compared to the deterministic case. However, the pattern is consistent enough that it cannot be dismissed as noise. In the recovery experiments, the differences were more noticeable but not consistent; while the presence of stochastic variables did consistently produce faster recovery times in some runs, it also produced much longer recovery times in other runs, without any consistency in the effect on average recovery time.
The reason stochasticity increases the resilience of the modeled system is due to the dual nature of the reinforcing feedback loops for species recruitment. If the regrowth rate is positive, then the reinforcing loop operates in a growth trajectory and repopulates/sustains the species despite fishing pressure. But if the regrowth rate is negative for a sustained period of time, then the loop enters a collapse trajectory with each year’s population being smaller than the last. In a deterministic model, this can create a trap, whereby the population is doomed to die out in the area being covered. However, when mature lifespan is stochastic, there are quite a few time periods where the regrowth rate is not only positive but quite high, as opposed to the deterministic scenario where the regrowth rate, depending on the harvest pressure, ends up being negative or only slightly positive. This finding is consistent with previous studies, which have drawn clear links between natural variability in growth rates and resilience (Ives 1995, Holling and Meffe 1996).
Our systematic analysis affirms that local communities can effectively govern common-pool resources, so long as access is controlled and rules are enforced (Cinti et al. 2010, Cinner 2011). The accord among the Seri social-ecological rules is critical to maintaining a resilient system even in the presence of environmental variability. These rules, rather than aiming to eliminate the variability in the system for the sake of maximizing harvest efficiency, actually protect the system from outside interference and enforce adaptive harvesting that respects the inherent variability in the system.
Our model left out several key areas for future studies. We did not attempt to directly incorporate how fluctuations in sale price affect relative fishing effort. The price data cited in Moreno et al. (2005) and that we collected for three time periods—2000–2001, 2004–2006, and 2009–2012—show that the price range is US$16–20 for
A. tuberculosa and US$5–6 for
P. rugosa, which suggests that the price structure is inelastic to supply and demand. The persistent price differential between the two species does impact fishing decisions, and this effect is incorporated into our model via Rule 3, which shifts effort between the two species along an OFT function. The Seri do choose either to allow outside fishers into the channel or to expel them. However, we do not model this fifth institutional rule in our model because it is driven by many complex factors exogenous to our model, such as the success of other Seri enterprises, financial transfers, and the changing demand of outside fishers to enter the channel, which is in turn driven by their local economies. In addition, more extensive experiments with wider ranges of stochasticity scenarios could also be conducted. The utility of a spatially explicit model representation should also be explored.
CONCLUSION
No one element, but the particular combination of different social-ecological rules and their interaction with the inherent environmental variability of the system, enables the resilience of the Seri artisanal fishery. This is in line with the view that multi-pronged approaches rather than simplistic policy prescriptions are needed in the management of complex systems. Small-scale fisheries or artisanal fisheries are for the most part multi-specific, but the management schemes are often designed as if they were mono-specific. We show that incorporating the variability in the system and the dynamics of each species of concern into the modeling effort can lead towards devising management and policy schemes that more comprehensively take into account factors that ensure a more sustainable future for these fisheries.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTSThis work is a culmination of a term project initiated by Jacobs and Duer-Balkind in the “Systems Modeling of the Environment” class offered by Güneralp at the Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies in 2009, and continued in 2010–2011 as an independent project under the sponsorship of Gordon Geballe. The authors thank the reviewers and participants at the 2011 International System Dynamics Conference for helpful comments on an earlier version of this paper, as well as the Ecology and Society anonymous reviewers for their constructive comments and suggestions. The authors thank Hannah Torres for the map, Luis Villanueva for his feedback, Newton Bueno for his work on the original mono-species system dynamics model of the Seri fishery, the Christensen Fund for financial support of Basurto’s research, and, of course, the Seri community for their continuing partnership.
LITERATURE CITED
Ahumada-Sempoal, M. A., S. J. Serrano-Guzmán, and N. Ruiz-García. 2002. Abundancia, estructura poblacional y crecimiento de
Atrina maura (Bivalvia: Pinnidae) en una laguna costera tropical del Pacífico mexicano.
Revista de Biología Tropical 50:1091–1100.
Aswani, S. 1998. The use of optimal foraging theory to assess the fishing strategies of Pacific Island artisanal fishers: a methodological review. Pages 19–26
in SPC Traditional Marine Resource Management and Knowledge Information Bulletin.
Balci, O. 1994. Validation, verification, and testing techniques throughout the life cycle of a simulation study.
Annals of Operations Research 53(1):121–173.
http://dx.doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02136828
Baqueiro, E., and M. Castagna. 1988. Fishery and culture of selected bivalves in Mexico: past, present and future.
Journal of Shellfish Research 7(3):433–443.
Barlas, Y. 1996. Formal aspects of model validity and validation in system dynamics.
System Dynamics Review 12:183–210.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/(SICI)1099-1727(199623)12:3<183::AID-SDR103>3.0.CO;2-4
Basurto, X. 2005. How locally designed access and use controls can prevent the tragedy of the commons in a Mexican small-scale fishing community.
Society & Natural Resources 18:643–659.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/08941920590959631
Basurto, X. 2006. Commercial diving and the Callo de Hacha fishery in Seri territory.
Journal of the Southwest 48:189–209.
Basurto, X. 2008. Biological and ecological mechanisms supporting marine self-governance: the Seri callo de hacha fishery in Mexico.
Ecology and Society 13(2): 20. [online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol13/iss2/art20/
Basurto, X., A. Cinti, L. Bourillón, M. Rojo, J. Torre, and A. H. Weaver. 2012. The emergence of access controls in small-scale fishing commons: a comparative analysis of individual licenses and common property-rights in two Mexican communities.
Human Ecology 40(4):597–609.
http://dx.doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s10745-012-9508-1
Beisner, B. E., D. T. Haydon, and K. Cuddington. 2003. Alternative stable states in ecology.
Frontiers in Ecology and Environment 1:376–382.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1890/1540-9295(2003)001[0376:ASSIE]2.0.CO;2
Béné, C. 2006.
Small-scale fisheries: assessing their contribution to rural livelihoods in developing countries. Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, Italy.
Béné, C., and A. Tewfik. 2001. Fishing effort allocation and fisherman’s decision making process in a multi-species small-scale fishery: analysis of the conch and lobster fishery in Turks and Caicos Islands.
Human Ecology 29:157–186.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1023/A:1011059830170
Berkes, F., R. Mahon, P. McConney, R. Pollnac, and R. Pomeroy. 2001.
Managing small-scale fisheries: alternative directions and methods. International Development Research Centre, Ottawa, Ontario, Canada.
Bueno, N., and X. Basurto. 2009. Resilience and collapse of artisanal fisheries: a system dynamics analysis of a shellfish fishery in the Gulf of California, Mexico.
Sustainability Science 4:139–149.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11625-009-0087-z
Cashore, B., and M. Howlett. 2007. Punctuating which equilibrium? Understanding thermostatic policy dynamics in Pacific Northwest forestry.
American Journal of Political Science 51(3):532–551.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-5907.2007.00266.x
Cinner, J. E. 2011. Social-ecological traps in reef fisheries.
Global Environmental Change 21:835–839.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2011.04.012
Cinner, J. E., T. R. McClanahan, N. A. J. Graham, T. M. Daw, J. Maina, S. M. Stead, A. Wamukota, K. Brown, and O. Bodin. 2012. Vulnerability of coastal communities to key impacts of climate change on coral reef fisheries.
Global Environmental Change 22:12–20.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2011.09.018
Cinti, A., W. Shaw, and J. Torre. 2010. Insights from the users to improve fisheries performance: fishers’ knowledge and attitudes on fisheries policies in Bahía de Kino, Gulf of California, Mexico.
Marine Policy 34:1322–1334.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.marpol.2010.06.005
Cudney-Bueno, J. R., and K. Rowell. 2008. Establishing a baseline for management of the rock scallop
Spondylus calcifer (Carpenter 1857): growth and reproduction in the Upper Gulf of California, Mexico.
Journal of Shellfish Research 27:625–632.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2983/0730-8000(2008)27[625:EABFMO]2.0.CO;2
Defeo, O., and J. C. Castilla. 2005. More than one bag for the world fishery crisis and keys for co-management successes in selected artisanal Latin American shellfisheries.
Reviews in Fish Biology and Fisheries 15:265–283.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11160-005-4865-0
Ford, A. 1999.
Modeling the environment: an introduction to system dynamics modeling of environmental systems. Island Press, Washington, D.C., USA.
Freire, J., and A. García-Allut. 2000. Socioeconomic and biological causes of management failures in European artisanal fisheries: the case of Galicia (NW Spain).
Marine Policy 24:375–384.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0308-597X(00)00013-0
Gelcich, S., T. P. Hughes, P. Olsson, C. Folke, O. Defeo, M. Fernández, S. Foale, L. H. Gunderson, C. Rodríguez-Sickert, M. Scheffer, R. S. Steneck, and J. C. Castilla. 2010. Navigating transformations in governance of Chilean marine coastal resources.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 107(39):16794–16799.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1012021107
Güneralp, B., and Y. Barlas. 2003. Dynamic modelling of a shallow freshwater lake for ecological and economic sustainability.
Ecological Modelling 167:115–138.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3800(03)00172-8
Gutiérrez, N. L., R. Hilborn, and O. Defeo. 2011. Leadership, social capital and incentives promote successful fisheries.
Nature 470:386–389.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/nature09689
Guttal, V., and C. Jayaprakash. 2007. Impact of noise on bistable ecological systems.
Ecological Modelling 201:420–428.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolmodel.2006.10.005
Halley, J. M. 1996. Ecology, evolution and 1/f-noise.
Trends in Ecology & Evolution 11:33–37.
http://dx.doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0169-5347(96)81067-6
Holling, C. S., and G. K. Meffe. 1996. Command and control and the pathology of natural resource management.
Conservation Biology 10:328–337.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1046/j.1523-1739.1996.10020328.x
Ives, A. R. 1995. Measuring resilience in stochastic systems.
Ecological Monographs 65:217–233.
http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/2937138
Ludwig, D., R. Hilborn, and C. Walters. 1993. Uncertainty, resource exploitation, and conservation: lessons from history.
Science 260:17–36.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.260.5104.17
Lutz, W., and K. C. Samir. 2010. Dimensions of global population projections: what do we know about future population trends and structures?
Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences 365(1554):2779–2791.
http://dx.doi.org/http://dx.doi.org/10.1098/rstb.2010.0133
McClanahan, T. R., N. A. J. Graham, M. A. MacNeil, N. A. Muthiga, J. E. Cinner, J. H. Bruggemann, and S. K. Wilson. 2011. Critical thresholds and tangible targets for ecosystem-based management of coral reef fisheries.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 108:17230–17233.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1106861108
Moreno, C., J. Torre, L. Bourillón, M. Durazo, A. H. Weaver, R. Barraza, and R. Castro. 2005. Estudio y evaluación de la pesquería de callo de hacha (
Atrina tuberculosa) en la Región de Bahía de Kino, Sonora y Recomendaciones para su Manejo. Page 27. Reporte interno.
Pauly, D. 2006. Major trends in small-scale marine fisheries, with emphasis on developing countries, and some implications for the social sciences.
Maritime Studies (MAST) 4:7–22.
Pineda, J. 2000. Linking larval settlement to larval transport: assumptions, potentials and pitfalls.
Oceanography of the Eastern Pacific 1:84–105.
Ricker, W. E. 1975. Computation and interpretation of biological statistics of fish populations.
Bulletin of the Fisheries Research Board of Canada 191:1–382.
Scheffer, M., S. Carpenter, J. A. Foley, C. Folke, and B. Walker. 2001. Catastrophic shifts in ecosystems.
Nature 413:591–596.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1038/35098000
Shelton, A. O., and M. Mangel. 2011. Fluctuations of fish populations and the magnifying effects of fishing.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 108:7075–7080.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1100334108
Siletic, T., and M. Peharda. 2003. Population study of the fan shell Pinna nobilis L. in Malo and Veliko Jezero of the Mljet National Park (Adriatic Sea).
Scientia Marina 67(1):91–98.
Stephens, D. W., and J. R. Krebs. 1986.
Foraging theory. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA.
Sterman, J. D. 2000.
Business dynamics: systems thinking and modeling for a complex world. Irwin/McGraw-Hill, Boston, Massachusetts, U.S.A.
Torre-Cosío, J., L. Bourillón-Moreno, A. Meking-López, and P. Ramírez-García. 2003. Distributional patterns of an annual eelgrass,
Zostera marina, population in the Gulf of California.
Gulf of Mexico Science 21:136.
Vicente, N., J. Moreteau, and P. Escoubet. 1980. Etude de l'evolution d'une population de Pinna nobilis L. (mollusque eulamellibranche) au large de l_anse de la Palud (Parc National sous-marin de Port-Cros).
Travaux Scientifiques du Parc national de Port-Cros 6:39–68.
Walker, B., C. S. Holling, S. R. Carpenter, and A. Kinzig. 2004. Resilience, adaptability and transformability in social–ecological systems.
Ecology and Society 9(2): 5. [online] URL:
http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol9/iss2/art5/
Young, O. R. 2010. Institutional dynamics: resilience, vulnerability, and adaptation in environmental and resource regimes.
Global Environmental Change 20:378–385.
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2009.10.001
Address of Correspondent:
Kasey R. Jacobs
International Institute of Tropical Forestry
Remote Sensing and GIS Laboratory
Calle Ceiba, San Juan
kasey.jacobs@aya.yale.edu