The following is the established format for referencing this article:
DeCaro, D. A., E. Frimpong Boamah, M. A. Rudolph, and G. A. Adusei. 2025. Maladaptive state reinforcement of greenspace in racially marginalized neighborhoods: lessons from Louisville, Kentucky’s failed cooperative extension partnership. Ecology and Society 30(2):3.ABSTRACT
Racially marginalized neighborhoods often lack equitable access to greenspace, despite government programs designed to provide this vital public good. We used the State-Reinforced Self-Governance (SRSG) Framework to evaluate and critique a failed greenspace decentralization program involving public–private partnership and community-based greenspace governance in Louisville, Kentucky, USA. State-reinforced self-governance involves decentralizing decision-making authority, empowering key stakeholders, and reinforcing their cooperation to manage feedback loops between public good provision and production. In doing so, the State (governments) seeks to enable sufficient authority, responsibility, and operational resources for polycentric self-governance. For 20 years, Louisville’s metro government informally sponsored a local administrative office of Kentucky’s Cooperative Extension Service—a federal/state program for agricultural research, education, and outreach—to oversee a community-based allotment garden program. We interviewed the program’s directors and analyzed its governing policies. We identified three major deficiencies in SRSG common to failed decentralization programs. First, the informal partnership lacked clearly defined, legally binding responsibilities—creating confusion and conflict. The partnership also lacked formal authorization and requirements for multi-actor cooperation (e.g., shared decision making, mutual monitoring)—undermining trust, collective problem solving, and compliance. Second, the Extension Office was underfunded and lacked essential operational capacities for land acquisition, protection, and management—creating a production crisis. Finally, as a subordinated administrative unit, the Office lacked authority to provision new policies to address known capacity limitations. These deficits severely limited the partnership’s transformative capacity, precipitating its collapse. According to the SRSG Framework, these arrangements exemplify a maladaptive, “responsibility-heavy” decentralization regime. Such systems are multi-centered but poorly coordinated and hierarchically governed. They impose responsibility on subordinate production agents under a guise of “polycentric self-governance,” without granting sufficient constitutional, administrative, or fiscal authority to function effectively. To facilitate theory development and institutional design, we contrast these arrangements with approaches that exemplify SRSG.
INTRODUCTION
Many cities lack small, community greenspaces for their health, recreation, and ecological benefit (Sun et al. 2022). Racially marginalized neighborhoods suffer most, inhabiting post-industrial areas characterized by concentrated poverty, public bads (e.g., industrial sites), and deficient public goods/services (Bullard and Johnson 2000, Green et al. 2016). This inequality often emerges from historic State oppression or neglect (Rigolon et al. 2018a,b). For example, in the USA, discriminatory federal policies (e.g., 1964 Highways Act) authorized city governments to raze Black neighborhoods for public infrastructure and private investments (e.g., highways, industrial facilities) that ultimately benefitted affluent White citizens. Many marginalized Black residents are trapped in barren industrial areas created by these policies (Gotham 2000, Connolly and Anguelovski 2021).
Many city governments are also trapped in a maladaptive cycle, unable to envision effective governance systems to disrupt strong social, economic, and legal barriers to greenspace transformation (e.g., Smith and Kurtz 2003, Chaffin et al. 2016b). To address this problem, some city governments have created innovative public–private partnerships using complex, polycentric community-based governance arrangements. These partnerships empower local governments and communities to co-provision (e.g., co-design) and co-produce (e.g., implement, maintain) neighborhood greenspace programs (e.g., Mattijssen et al. 2018, Anderson et al. 2019; cf. Colding et al. 2013, Schifman et al. 2017). These systems exhibit evidence of adaptive and transformative governance (ATG) (Garmestani et al. 2019) but are difficult to implement because their design features are poorly understood (Schukoske 2000, DeCaro et al. 2025a).
In the current paper, we analyze a case of maladaptive polycentric greenspace provision and production, using the State-reinforced self-governance (SRSG) framework of ATG (DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b). The case takes place in Louisville, Kentucky—a post-industrial city in the USA with pronounced racial segregation and greenspace disparity (Gilderbloom 2016, Parks and People Foundation (PPF) 2000). It is especially informative because it features a common solution—partnership with the Cooperative Extension Service (a federal/state program for agricultural outreach) (Diekmann et al. 2017, Ruemenapp 2017)—that failed to ensure positive outcomes. The system exhibits the hallmarks of a classic but poorly understood decentralization failure, dysfunctional cooperation and devolution of responsibility to a capacity-deprived agent (Ribot et al. 2006, Andersson and Ostrom 2008). We explain how the system emerged and why it failed to effectively govern and maintain greenspaces in marginalized neighborhoods from a contextual and institutional design standpoint.
This study is part of a larger project (DeCaro et al. 2025b) examining how governments enable (or constrain) ATG by facilitating (or impeding) diverse forms of self-governance. The SRSG framework posits that governments can facilitate ATG in decentralized systems by supporting dilemma stakeholders’ capacity for independent action, organizational self-governance, and-actor cooperation—creating a polycentric, self-governing system for collective problem solving and institutional innovation. Therefore, we investigate larger theoretical issues relevant to decentralization, polycentricity, State power, and (co)provision/(co)production of environmental public goods in metropolitan systems (cf. Oakerson 1999, Ostrom 2000, Shivakumar 2005, Wang and Liang 2024).
In doing so, we also address three methodological deficits in the assessment of ATG that hinder scientific advancement and undermine policy design (DeCaro et al. 2025b). Scientists and policy makers often focus on a single timeframe (Baldwin et al. 2024). The current study examines a 20-yr time period to better understand institutional emergence, evolution, and resilience over time. Prior research often oversimplifies complex systems, overlooking critical components, processes, and interactions, such as feedback loops between (co)provisioning and (co)production (McGinnis 2011, Baldwin et al. 2024). This study examines these structural and functional connections to better understand how polycentric networks of provision/production (Ostrom 1994, Oakerson 1999) facilitate or impede one another—contributing to system flexibility or rigidity (Barnes et al. 2017, Baldwin et al. 2024). Third, this study helped to develop the SRSG framework’s coding system, contributing to assessment of SRSG and adaptive/transformative capacity (Engle 2011, Siders 2019, Clement et al. 2021). This approach addresses the call for greater scientific rigor in the study of ATG systems (Ostrom 2005a, Cumming et al. 2020, Baldwin et al. 2024, DeCaro et al. 2025b).
We start by describing the historical and technical characteristics of the dilemma. We then overview concepts of co-provision and co-production relevant to this study, especially provision–production feedback loops that influence (mal)adaptation. Afterward, we discuss the SRSG framework, outlining the analytical conventions and hypotheses guiding our work. The methods and results highlight governance structures, processes, and capacities affecting important outcomes—including greenspace access and system resilience. We conclude with scientific and practical implications for SRSG and ATG.
CHARACTERIZING THE DILEMMA
Greenspace access is affected by numerous actors, factors, and processes (Schifman et al. 2017). Greenspace inequality poses several interlocking subdilemmas pertaining to greenspace governance (provision), and resource management/allocation (production) (Sharifi 2016, Foster and Iaone 2016). These dilemmas span institutional, ecological, built, and sociopolitical infrastructures (Chaffin et al. 2016b). This complexity—and structural racism—is why so few cities adequately resolve the problem (Cahn and Segal 2016). This complexity is also why novel research frameworks and methods are needed to gain analytical leverage over such systems (Cumming et al. 2020, Baldwin et al. 2024, DeCaro et al. 2025b).
Historical background
Deficient greenspace in the USA’s marginalized neighborhoods emerged from deliberate State oppression and misguided urban planning that emphasized industrialization, suburbanization, and large central parks that serve predominantly affluent White citizens (Sharifi 2016, Connolly and Anguelovski 2021; for global perspective, Sun et al. 2022). From 1900–1970, minoritized citizens were subjected to federal, state, and local laws that systematically robbed their communities of land and property, and disenfranchised their political and economic rights (e.g., Jim Crow laws). The 1924 National Housing Act, 1954 federal Housing Act, and 1964 Highways Act encouraged so-called “redlining” and “urban renewal.” Local governments, banks, insurance companies, and real-estate agencies conspired to officially designate minority-owned households and neighborhoods as “blighted” (Gotham 2000, Pritchett 2003). This designation authorized businesses to deny essential services (e.g., bank loans), and permitted governments to forcibly take property (seizure by eminent domain). Neighborhoods were razed to install highways and other public works benefiting White residents.
Greenspace inequalities emerged from these and ongoing forms of systemic racism (e.g., Smiley et al. 2014; see Nardone et al. 2021 for review). In Louisville, these factors were compounded by devastating floods in 1937 and 1945, especially in Louisville’s West End. White residents received loans to rebuild or relocate. Black residents did not, worsening neighborhood decline and producing the current greenspace wasteland (Marshall 2017, Mattingly 2021).
Technical characteristics
Equitable greenspace access is a complex social-ecological dilemma, posing several sub-dilemmas and action situations, or centers of decision making and operational activity. Ostrom (1990) suggested that such complex dilemmas typically pose at least one common-pool resource (CPR) dilemma and two associated public good (PG) dilemmas: (1) creating a governance system (provision), and (2) performing technical procedures to deliver and maintain necessary infrastructures, goods, and services (production) (cf. Anderies et al. 2016). The current dilemma exhibits these elements at the city and neighborhood levels (Fig. 1). These aspects of greenspace provision and production are tightly linked and must be addressed simultaneously as a complex sociotechnical network or system to understand the system’s dynamics and performance (e.g., Schifman et al. 2017; cf. Anderies et al. 2016).
We focus primarily on the city-level provisioning dilemma, and secondarily on production activities at intermediate and neighborhood levels. Specifically, we investigate whether and how cities such as Louisville can provision city-wide community-greenspace programs capable of effectively producing community-greenspace access and management services over time. This focus also entails examining the responsiveness of the system to interlocking provision–production crises (Oakerson 1999, Anderies et al. 2016).
At the city level, there is a CPR dilemma regarding land scarcity and allocation (Cahn and Segal 2016, Foster and Iaone 2016). Cities are densely populated hubs of economic activity and development (“land-use”) within a confined geographic location (Grimm et al. 2008). City governments typically prioritize profitable development projects, not community greenspace—especially in marginalized neighborhoods that generate little tax revenue for public works (Smith and Kurtz 2003, Sharifi 2016). City governments must create governance systems to oversee city-wide land use, prioritizing and enabling equitable greenspace (PG dilemma; cf. PPF 2000). These institutional arrangements must codify such aspects as to which lands are eligible, who will produce and govern the sites, and how site management will be enforced. Potential greenspaces must also be acquired and processed into usable form (e.g., clearing deeds/titles, property tax payment) and maintained throughout the city (PG dilemma).
At the neighborhood level, a CPR dilemma occurs when allocating limited room for garden plots and other uses (e.g., recreation) within each greenspace site. Competition among gardeners and/or community members must be addressed, and a governance system created to govern each site (PG), whether community governed or otherwise (Colding et al. 2013, Mattijssen et al. 2018). Finally, each greenspace (and its plots) must be maintained, satisfying landscape and public health requirements (PG) (Kirshbaum 2000).
Governing and maintaining public goods/services such as community greenspaces that are dispersed throughout a city poses significant logistical and financial challenges (see Oakerson 1999, Ostrom 2000 for discussion of scale). Few park departments can address these challenges alone. Bridge organizations and public–private partnership are often needed, enabling government and non-government stakeholders (e.g., non-profit organizations, communities) to co-provision and co-produce necessary goods/services via various polycentric arrangements (Chaffin et al. 2016b, Schifman et al. 2017). We discuss these considerations next, foreshadowing our application of SRSG.
CO-PROVISION, CO-PRODUCTION, AND RESILIENCE
Governance and State power are fundamentally about determining the means of provision (e.g., governance) and production in society (Ostrom 1980, 2010a). The current paper seeks to understand how SRSG is related to such provision–production networks in ATG systems.
(Co)provision and (co)production
The concepts of (co)provision and (co)production are debated (Ostrom 1996, Voorberg et al. 2014). We use terms by Oakerson (1999). “Provisioning” refers to activities to decide and create institutions (“rules of the game”) and governance systems. “Production” refers to technical activities to deliver various goods/services to address particular dilemmas. Co-provision and co-production are collective forms of provision and production. Maladaptive systems emerge from misfit and dysfunction in the design and implementation of these system elements (Anderies et al. 2016, DeCaro et al. 2025b).
Regarding production, scholars and practitioners have identified several critical production activities (i.e., operational capacities) needed for community greenspace (e.g., Kirshbaum 2000, PPF 2000, Schukoske 2000). For example, successful greenspace programs must be designed to effectively and efficiently acquire land (e.g., titling), protect the greenspaces against redevelopment, and ensure site upkeep (see Table 1). Due to the diversity of services and dynamic nature of urban systems, complex multi-stakeholder networks of provisioners and producers are often needed to deliver and maintain these goods.
Provision–production networks
(Co)provision and (co)production are linked by feedback loops (Morgan and England 1988, Barnes et al. 2017). Effective polycentric ATG systems ensure that key stakeholders have sufficient capacity to independently and jointly govern these feedbacks. In these systems, provision and production units fulfill complementary roles—independently and/or collectively altering institutional structures, functions, and/or processes to address shortfalls or crises in performance of their independent and joint duties (Oakerson 1999, Baldwin et al. 2024). This principle implies that key stakeholders in decentralized systems require some degree of independent and joint capacity for self-governance, production, and multi-actor cooperation (McGinnis 2011, Baldwin et al. 2024, DeCaro et al. 2025b). There may also be synergies and trade-offs among these capacities (Oakerson 1999).
For example, consider a case where a critically important production unit (e.g., parks department) lacks necessary production capacities (i.e., Table 1). The unit could resolve these shortfalls through (a) self-governance within its own unit (provisioning its own institutional solutions) or (b) multi-actor cooperation and collective self-governance (co-provisioning and/or co-producing institutional and technical solutions with other stakeholders) (cf. Ostrom 2005a, Morgan and England 1988, McGinnis 2011). If the unit lacks capacity for organizational self-governance, and/or collective self-governance is deficient, then rigidity traps may emerge at organizational and/or system levels—resulting in failed greenspace provision/production. Such traps are common in maladaptive decentralization systems (Andersson and Ostrom 2008, Cumming 2018). The SRSG framework was developed to provide conceptual, analytical, and methodological leverage over these issues.
STATE-REINFORCED SELF-GOVERNANCE FRAMEWORK
The SRSG framework examines the role governments play in enabling (or hindering) effective and resilient polycentric, self-governing systems (DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b). There are many conceptualizations of polycentricity and resilience (Siders 2017, Baldwin et al. 2024). The SRSG framework offers one perspective. It seeks to explain the underlying structural and procedural features of polycentric systems (e.g., design principles, network structures, provision/production processes) that affect ATG and resilience. We begin by defining ATG, followed by adaptive and transformative capacity, and the SRSG perspective.
Adaptive and transformative governance
Within Ostrom political economy, ATG systems are societal problem-solving systems characterized by diverse centers of activity, which share information, experiment, and alter their institutional structures, functions, and processes to jointly address common problems (Ostrom 1994, 2005a,b; see Chaffin et al. 2014, 2016a). Self-organization, adaptive decision making, and multi-actor cooperation are essential features of ATG, enabling diverse stakeholders to understand their dilemma(s), build trust, and problem solve to devise better-fitting solutions to complex and dynamic social-ecological dilemmas (Ostrom 1990, 2005a). These functions emerge from underlying sets of institutional features and capacities.
Adaptive and transformative capacity
From a systems perspective, adaptive and transformative capacities (ATC) refer to properties of social-ecological systems (SESs) that enable them to adjust (adapt) or innovate and replace (transform) existing components (structures, functions, and/or processes) to address stressors or crises (Garmestani et al. 2019). Institutionally, ATCs are properties of governance systems that enable them to adapt or transform institutional arrangements to address feedback loops and emergent needs for (co)provision and (co)production (DeCaro et al. 2025b).
In the SRSG framework, institutional ATCs are embodied by design principles, such as authority for organizational and/or collective self-governance, which give stakeholders the capability to (a) produce various goods/services and (b) make decisions to alter institutional arrangements. State-reinforced self-governance seeks to describe how governments use their legislative, administrative, regulatory, and fiscal powers to in/formally enable (or constrain) these capacities in complex provision–production networks (Sarker 2013, DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b). The SRSG framework diagnoses and explains the ATC of ATG systems in terms of three core components: design principles, institutional archetypes, and governance networks.
Design principles
The SRSG framework regards institutional design principles (Table 2) as the functional building blocks (“elements”) of institutions, which therefore represent their fundamental ATCs. For example, Ostrom’s (1990, 2005a) design principles for multi-actor cooperation (e.g., shared decision making, enforcement) facilitate information exchange and trust, enabling cooperative problem solving among diverse stakeholders, thereby increasing their collective ATC. Design principles for State-reinforcement (DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b) refer to authority (powers), responsibilities (duties, constraints), operational resources (e.g., funding), and mechanisms for flexibility/stability (e.g., decision-making discretion, policy sunsets) that are in/formally granted or assigned to particular actors and collective action processes. These authorizations, responsibilities, and resources further enable (or constrain) actors’ independent and collective ATC in the form of enhanced (or diminished) capacity for production of particular goods/services, organizational self-governance, or collective self-governance.
For example, governments may (a) create new organizations, with particular sets of powers and duties, (b) forbid particular organizations from governing themselves, and/or (c) authorize actors to engage in various forms of multi-actor cooperation (e.g., communication, shared decision making), to address particular kinds of social-ecological dilemmas. These State actions enable emergence and resilience of some kinds of provision–production networks, while constraining others (Ostrom 1994, 2010a). These actions fundamentally affect the ATC of individual actors, collectives, and the system as a whole (DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b).
The effect(s) of design principles are configural and interact with social-ecological context in complex ways (Crawford and Ostrom 2005, McGinnis and Ostrom 2014). The SRSG framework uses the concept of institutional archetypes, organizational self-governance, and governance network structure to account for this complexity.
Institutional archetypes
Institutional archetypes refer to prototypical institutional forms or “entities,” including types of rules (Ostrom and Crawford 2005), particular roles or types of actors (Tarko et al. 2019), common organizations (Carper and Snizek 1980), and governance network structures (Barnes et al. 2017, Schifman et al. 2017). In the current study, we focus primarily on organizational archetypes and their underlying, archetypal capacities. Specifically, various types of organizations possess different configurations of institutional capacities, which enable them to perform particular functions.
The SRSG framework developed a Base 3 Typology of ATC to enable analysts to classify the basic ATCs associated with particular institutional entities (DeCaro et al. 2025b). For example, what ATCs does a typical (or specific) non-profit organization, parks department, or extension office possess? What capacities do particular types of multi-actor cooperatives (e.g., partnerships), or collective action processes possess? These underlying capacities are conceptualized by examining prototypical configurations of authority, responsibility, and operational resources. The SRSG framework also considers a focal actor’s degree of organizational self-governance, which is a subset of an organization’s archetypal capacities (Ostrom 1992, McGinnis 2017). Generally speaking, particular actors in a decentralized network need particular capacities for organizational self-governance, collective self-governance (e.g., multi-actor cooperation), and the provision and/or production of specific goods/services.
The SRSG framework (DeCaro et al. 2025b) identifies four basic archetypes in terms of ATC. Two are especially informative for the current study. The Reinforced (A+R+) archetype refers to entities that have sufficient formal (legally binding) authority and responsibility to perform necessary provision and/or production activities, for their role(s) in a particular dilemma. For example, non-profit organizations (NPOs) are a common organizational archetype, with particular capacities. Non-profit organizations are typically authorized to perform a variety of operational functions relevant to particular service mission(s) (Lane 1980), like public education, environmental protection, or community greenspace (DeCaro et al. 2025a). Many NPOs act as bridge organizations, with authority to engage in multi-actor cooperation (e.g., communication, shared decision making) with diverse stakeholders. Non-profit organizations have formal mandates (responsibilities) that compel them to fulfill their mission(s) and prohibit them from engaging in activities that may undermine their mission for public service (e.g., political lobbying, profit seeking). Reinforced entities are thought to facilitate effective operations, especially when they have sufficient external resources (E+) and self-sufficiency (SS+) to ensure fiscal autonomy and resilience (cf. Kemper et al. 2007, Andersson and Ostrom 2008).
In contrast, Responsibility-heavy entities (A-R+) have formal responsibility to perform particular functions but insufficient authority. For example, a decentralized administrative office may be formally required to acquire and promote community-governed greenspace but lack the necessary administrative or operational capacities (authority). DeCaro and colleagues (2017, 2025b) suggest this type of deficiency is common in maladaptive decentralization systems (cf. Ribot et al. 2006). Such arrangements may be especially dysfunctional when the focal actor (e.g., decentralized unit) is a subordinate actor (e.g., agency, office) that receives orders and most of its funding from a higher, supervisory agent (cf. Kemper et al. 2007). Such archetypes are classified as an A-R+EE+SS- subtype: a responsibility-heavy entity with high external resource dependency (EE+) and low self-sufficiency (SS-). Such entities generally have low fiscal and decision-making autonomy, greatly reducing their ATC. DeCaro et al. (2025b) suggest that this archetypal configuration of ATCs may be especially problematic when the focal actor needs to perform diverse provision and/or production functions in a complex, dynamic SES or dilemma (cf. Anderies et al. 2016).
Organizational self-governance
The SRSG framework distinguishes organizational self-governance from multi-actor cooperation (e.g. collective self-governance) and (co)production (DeCaro et al. 2025b). Whereas capacities for multi-actor cooperation (Table 2) facilitate cooperative modes of self-governance (and ATC), organizational self-governance facilitates independent (organizational) forms of self-governance (and ATC). Specifically, actors with greater constitutive, constitutional decision-making, rule-making, administrative, self-regulatory, and fiscal authority (Table 3) typically have greater discretion, and therefore ATC (Ostrom 1992, McGinnis 2017). Non-profit organizations typically possess these capacities, allowing them to adopt or reconfigure their organizational structures, missions, functions, and processes to better address changing conditions (Lane 1980, Singh et al. 2022). This adaptability is why NPOs are prominent figures in ATG systems.
Synergies and trade-offs
Synergic relationships among actors’ positions and capacities generally improve a system’s ATC, with different functional nodes enhancing the strengths, and compensating for the deficiencies, of others (Oakerson 1999, Baldwin et al. 2024). Maladaptive governance systems typically feature (a) contextually inappropriate organizational and/or ATC archetypes that lack necessary production capacities (Table 1), (b) deficient multi-actor cooperation (Table 2), and/or (c) hierarchical governance arrangements that overly restrict the focal decentralized actor’s capacity for organizational self-governance (Table 3) (DeCaro et al. 2025a,b). As shown later, the current case exhibits deficiencies in all three dimensions.
Formality
The ATC of governance systems is affected by both formal (de jure) “rules on paper” and informal (de facto) “rules in use” (Crawford and Ostrom 2005). Formal and informal institutional arrangements may mis/align in complementary or contradictory ways. For example, informally granted decision-making authority could enable an actor to overcome deficits in formal authority. Alternatively, informal State-imposed restrictions on decision-making authority could prevent an actor from operating as formally intended (Hosseinioon 2019, Jaffe and Koster 2019). Either situation could yield dis/advantageous outcomes (Garmestani et al. 2019). The effects of in/formality depends on context. DeCaro et al. (2025b) therefore advise analysts to examine formal and informal institutional arrangements to understand their potential consequences for ATG—especially when informal arrangements are prominent in a particular system. As described later, the current case involves many critical informal components. We therefore analyze both the formal and informal arrangements structuring the case.
Governance network and institutional fit
The SRSG framework uses an updated version of McGinnis and Ostrom’s (2014) SES framework to understand how context influences the fit (adequacy, appropriateness) and performance of particular network configurations. An important factor to consider is whether key actors possess synergistic roles and capacities within the decentralized system. For example, many ATG systems feature a bridge organization, which serves as a center for collective decision making, coordination, and multi-stakeholder cooperation (e.g., co-provision, co-production) (Garmestani and Benson 2013, Barnes et al. 2017). Such entities presumably need sufficient authority, responsibility, and operational resources for multi-actor cooperation. Adaptive and transformative governance systems also feature rule makers and regulators, which benefit from specific capacities (Epstein 2017). The SRSG framework asks how the State facilitates emergence and coordination of these centers and modes of activity for particular SESs and dilemmas. We used the SRSG-SES framework to contextualize the case-study system and subsequent analyses.
CASE STUDY SYSTEM
This study examines a failed community-greenspace system, involving a multi-level, multi-stakeholder partnership among Louisville Metro Government (LMG), the University of Kentucky’s (UK) state Extension Service, the local office of Louisville/Jefferson County’s Cooperative Extension Service (JCCE Office), and local communities. The JCCE Office is a bridge organization sponsored by LMG (and UK) to coordinate key stakeholders and administer LMG’s community-greenspace program. Thus, JCCE Office is the primary decentralized unit responsible for the program’s core functions.
To facilitate contextual understanding and ground our formal analyses, we first provide a narrative description of the system. This description includes the context and major governance arrangements, events, and outcomes. Afterward, we report our methods and formal analysis, explaining the factors, technical design features, and interactions driving the case.
Louisville
Louisville, Kentucky is a moderately sized, post-industrial metropolitan region in the USA. Its historical, economic, and racial characteristics resemble other midwestern cities facing similar greenspace dilemmas (e.g., Smiley et al. 2014, Green et al. 2016). The Louisville Metro Area ranks 27th in the nation by population (633,000; 67% White/Caucasian, 24% Black/African American) (U.S. Census Bureau 2021). Median household income is $58,000 (16% poverty rate).
Louisville is among the USA’s most segregated cities (Acs et al. 2017, Mattingly 2021). Approximately 77% of Black residents inhabit Louisville’s West End (median household income: $24,000). This area experiences greater exposure to public bads (e.g. brownfields, air pollution; Sarr et al. 2021), decreased lifespans (Gilderbloom et al. 2016), and greater income, housing, and public infrastructure disparity (Croutcher 2017, Marshall 2017). During the study period, there were 6000–7000 vacant properties. Most (60%) were in the West End (Nelson 2017, Vacant and Abandoned Property Administration (VPPA) 2018). Vacant properties decreased to approximately 2000 units recently, but the majority remain concentrated in the West End. Louisville prioritizes large parks and therefore lacks a comprehensive greenspace plan for small, neighborhood greenspaces. Thus, only about 37% of Louisville’s population can access a recreational area or greenspace within a 10-min (0.8 km) walk from their residence (Trust for Public Land (TPL) 2023).
Extension service
Cooperative Extension Service is a federal program created in 1862 (Morrill Act), and updated in 1914 (Smith-Lever Act), to support agricultural production via agricultural research and development, education, partnership, and outreach (Diekmann et al. 2017, Ruemenapp 2017). It provides federal funds and land for states to establish “land-grant universities,” which implement a state’s extension programs. Kentucky’s Extension Service is organized by county/district. Each of Kentucky’s 120 counties may create an Extension District, with an office for service delivery. Offices are governed by a county Extension Council and Board of Directors.
University of Kentucky is Kentucky’s flagship land-grant university. It is located approximately 113 km east of Louisville/Jefferson County. University of Kentucky’s Extension Director is therefore the state director, planning and overseeing state-wide extension activities under supervision of Kentucky’s Secretary of Agriculture, in collaboration with local/county extension offices (Cooperative Extension Services (CES) 2024). University of Kentucky’s Extension Director is also advised by a state-level Extension Advisory council, consisting of representatives from major regions in Kentucky. University of Kentucky’s Extension Director wields executive (e.g., constitutional, regulatory) powers over extension offices and programs. Thus, county extension services and their offices are semi-autonomous: they operate within the constitutional constraints (rules, regulations) determined by UK’s Extension Director and federal, state, and local laws.
Extension Services are intended to be decentralized, self-governing entities to enable (a) local implementation of state-wide initiatives and (b) locally adaptive decision making, to create programs and solutions that are responsive to local needs (Franz and Townson 2008). Extension offices often play a supportive role in urban agriculture/community greenspace, providing agricultural training, technological expertise, equipment, and supplies (e.g., raised garden beds). They may also help coordinate various non/government stakeholders for particular projects (Reynolds 2011, Ruemenapp 2017). However, they typically do not serve as the principal agent (decentralized unit) responsible for administering a city’s greenspace program(s). The Louisville case exhibits several features that depart substantially from this norm.
Louisville/Jefferson County extension
The greenspace partnership system is complex, involving many loosely coordinated actors and poorly specified governance roles and processes (Fig. 2). It is complex partly because the stakeholders failed to devise a cohesive and efficient solution that supports an effective network for co-provision and co-production of critical goods/services.
Unlike other extension offices, JCCE Office is a direct satellite of UK’s Extension Service. The Office operates in Louisville but is staffed by UK employees. It has a local administrative Director but is governed by UK’s Director and the JCCE District Board (Fig. 2a-b), which is this Extension District’s governing body. The Board has seven members: Louisville’s Mayor and six local “citizens” appointed by the Mayor, representing public agricultural, economic, and community interests. The Board is advised by a Council of at least 15 additional citizens (Fig. 2c). However, UK’s Extension Director can override decisions made by any district, board/council, or office.
Kentucky’s Extension Service is therefore structurally decentralized, with opportunity for public advisory input, but is governed hierarchically. The JCCE Office is a subordinate administrative unit within this system. The Office implements programmatic decisions made by its governing bodies, JCCE District (Board, Council), UK, and UK’s Extension Director.
In 2003, LMG and Jefferson County merged into a larger metro region. Louisville Metro Government and UK entered an official agreement (memorandum of agreement (MOA)) at this time. The MOA established JCCE Office’s modern operations, which officially pertain to standard extension services (agriculture research/development, education, outreach). Louisville Metro Government also became a supervisory agent (Fig. 2d) for the Office, and officially agreed to provide JCCE Office $350,000 annually for its general operations. University of Kentucky and UK’s Extension Director agreed to provide staff salary support, training, equipment, and primary administrative oversight.
Community-greenspace partnership
The greenspace partnership/community-greenspace program formed around 2005. The precise date cannot be determined because the partnership was created by an informal verbal agreement among unknown agents (Fig. 2e). There are no records of the agreement or who formed it. As will become clear later, this informality misaligns problematically with Extension’s formal federal, state, and local mandates, detrimentally affecting the greenspace program.
Interviews with key stakeholders indicate that JCCE Office was asked to oversee 11 (now 10) community greenspaces, sponsored by LMG’s allotment garden program (Fig. 2f). The greenspaces are primarily food-producing gardens, dispersed throughout Louisville/Jefferson County. Gardeners pay a small annual fee (e.g., $20) to use a private garden plot. The JCCE Office was informally authorized to use $50,000 of its annual funding for the program. Louisville Metro Government (i.e., the Mayor’s legal council) created a Community Garden Agreement delineating gardeners’ rights and responsibilities toward greenspace management. The JCCE Office is charged with the responsibility to convey and enforce the garden agreement.
Importantly, the official MOA among LMG, UK, and JCCE Office does not mention the greenspace partnership or community-greenspace program (JCCE Office Director). This informality makes the program’s institutional arrangements and operations uncertain:
[W]e have a...verbally grandfathered agreement to operate in those [green]spaces. [B]ut we do not have anything legally binding or current.... [W]e have a system of quiet anarchy where people—because there’s so much that is nebulous in this system—that folks have learned to operate on a basic level, and just do things that generally fall within what has been culturally deemed acceptable. (JCCE Office Horticulture Agent)
To ensure efficient site management, JCCE Office was asked to sponsor local communities to govern and maintain the greenspaces via a community-based approach (Fig. 2g). Specifically, JCCE Office would provide technical and educational support, like leadership training and occasional supplies. In 2013—several years into the partnership—JCCE Office helped a transgovernmental collaborative create a flagship demonstration garden, Parkland Community Garden, which was envisioned as the template for future sites (Department of Economic Growth and Innovation (DEGI) 2013). A LMG staff member described the project’s purpose:
Parkland Community Garden was...a Metro owned lot. It had been vacant for 20 or 30 years.... [S]ome neighbors in Parkland had talked to [their Councilperson] and had wanted a garden.... [University of Louisville’s Center for Environmental Policy and Management] negotiated with [a Senior Policy staff member in LMG], who was doing the local food at that time—[this person] helped to get the lot secured. JCCE provided...soil, they provided cedar logs for the actual beds, and the mulch.... [B]ut the idea with any garden that we [LMG] support...there’s got to be enough local support that it’s self-sustaining. So we don’t really want to need to be involved to keep it going. The idea is that the neighborhood has ownership of it, and they kind of keep things running.... So JCCE helps, you know, with just basic management...keeping the water turned on and all that sort of thing.
Interviews indicate that JCCE Office was initially supportive of local community governance and management. However, JCCE struggled to maintain community stewardship, resulting in poor site upkeep and neighborhood complaints for some greenspaces, triggering external enforcement by local district councilpersons, LMG, and UK’s Extension Director. The JCCE Office eventually took control of site governance and maintenance to guarantee their upkeep. The JCCE Office’s Director said the following about Parkland:
[T]he Parkland Community Garden ended up being via [local Councilperson], the community that developed their own core group. [T]hey wanted control over the community garden, and because of our investment, we couldn’t let them have full control. We said, “Let’s partner on this.” [B]ecause of our liability in the [lease] agreement that we signed, we have to make [sure] that at least that part of the agreement is maintained.
The JCCE Office’s Horticultural Agent, who became responsible for directly maintaining (e.g., mowing) each greenspace site, confirmed similar arrangements for the other sites:
[T]he community does not have any agency in determining structure and management. It’s all very hierarchical...there’s not a lot of agency or role for gardeners in decision making... It’s kind of a landlord/tenant relationship, where we become the landlords.
The JCCE Office’s decision to take over site management strained its financial and operational capacities, preventing it from acquiring new sites.
Greenspace equity
To understand the implications of this decision for greenspace equity, we conducted a spatial analysis assessing the program’s greenspace access for marginalized communities (see Appendix 1 for details). We examined 2010 (5-yr) demographic estimates from the U.S. Census’s American Community Survey database, determining the percentage of Black, White, and other individuals of low vs. high income status living within a 0.8 km radius (10-min walk) from each sponsored site. Most (40%) of the sites (n = 4) serve majority White high-income areas (Fig. 3). An additional 20% (n = 2) serve White low-income communities in the West End. Only 30% (n = 3) serve majority Black low-income areas (10%, n = 1, serve Black high-income areas). Thus, few of the sponsored greenspaces serve marginalized Black communities.
In nearly 20 yrs, the greenspace program did not expand beyond 10 sites or robustly address inequitable access. Stakeholder interviews indicate that most of the greenspaces are fenced and closed to the community, usable only by fee-paying gardeners. Moreover, the greenspaces are not community governed or maintained. In May 2024, the Mayor’s Office issued a proposal to defund JCCE Office (minus $300,000), with $50,000 remaining to support the existing greenspaces until an alternative solution is developed. Interviews identified several contributing factors, including financial constraints, lack of community governance to enable cost-efficient site management, and various capacity limitations of JCCE Office and the partnership. Interviews also revealed that JCCE Office was not only heavily dependent on LMG and UK for its funding, but also administratively subordinated to LMG and UK.
These patterns suggest potential involvement of a maladaptive, resource-dependent responsibility-heavy (A-R+EE+SS-) governance regime, with a lack of organizational self-governance by the focal actor JCCE Office, and deficient multi-actor cooperation. To determine whether and how these features contributed, we conducted a technical analysis of the institutional arrangements and design features structuring the system. This analysis reveals precise mechanisms by which this attempted polycentric ATG system failed, providing insight into SRSG and ATG of complex social-ecological dilemmas.
METHODS
The current case system sought to facilitate equitable greenspace via decentralized public–private partnership. The local Extension office (JCCE Office), served as the focal decentralization unit and bridge organization. This actor (JCCE Office) was also given primary (co)provision and (co)production responsibilities. Therefore, we focus our analysis primarily on this actor, asking the extent to which it has sufficient capacity for greenspace production, organizational self-governance, and multi-actor cooperation to co-provision and co-produce equitable greenspace with its partners in this complex provision–production network.
Design
We examined the time period 2005–2020, with some recent observations from 2024. This period spans the greenspace program’s formation and collapse. During Phase 1 (July–November 2017), we collected initial policy documents, websites, news articles, and interviews to develop a preliminary understanding of the case. During Phase 2 (June 2019–January 2020), we collected additional interviews and policy documents. We acquired policy and organizational documents from the public domain (e.g., government databases, websites) and requested others.
Codes derived from these data, and anonymized interview data that support the findings of this study, are openly available in OSF [https://osf.io/7t4am/?view_only=2d716009d89b4282b9758ee3ebac3f39]. Ethical approval for this research study was granted by the principal investigator’s university human subjects institutional review board (IRB 17.0723, 19.0588). All interviewers and data analysts were certified for adherence to ethical standards to protect human data. The interviewees participated voluntarily, with informed consent.
Policy documents
We collected the following policy documents: Morrill Act 1862/1980 (establishing the federally sponsored Land Grant/Agricultural Research program), Smith-Lever Act 1914/2008 (establishing the Cooperative Extension Service); Kentucky Revised Statues (KRS) 164 (establishing Kentucky’s Extension Service and University of Kentucky as its primary administrative center); Ordinance 36-2002/119-2007 (establishing the modern Extension Service in Louisville/Jefferson County); MOA (formal partnership agreement between Louisville Metro Government, the University of Kentucky, and the local extension service); University of Kentucky’s Extension bylaws; and the greenspace program’s Community Garden Agreement (governing garden-user rights and responsibilities). We also examined Kentucky’s state constitution for an environmental bill of rights that may support greenspace rights (non-existent); Louisville’s sustainability plans; and information about greenspace programs that facilitate purchase/stewardship of vacant lots for community greenspace.
Participants
We interviewed 11 informants familiar with the creation and/or administration of the greenspace partnership and its community-greenspace program: Louisville’s Extension Office Director (JCCE1), horticulture-garden agent (JCCE2), and an Extension Councilperson who was also familiar with Louisville’s first market garden (LOF1); two senior personnel (LF1, LF2) in LMG’s economic and community development agency, Louisville Forward, who were involved in urban agriculture policy; a senior personnel (OCD1) in Louisville’s Land Bank Authority (overseeing city-owned vacant lots) and LMG’s Office of Community Development (formerly Vacant/Public Properties Administration); and two senior personnel of the Metropolitan Sewer District (MSD1, MSD2), a prominent land-owner.
Three additional interviews provided background information about community greenspace, political economy, and stewardship in Louisville: a senior personnel of the Louisville-Jefferson County Environmental Land Trust (LJCELT1), a governmental land trust that preserves large-scale rural/agricultural sites; Director of a NPO specializing in urban greening, volunteer coordination, and some community-greenspace management (LG1); and Program Director (CEG1) for a church-based, charitable organization overseeing some community-greenspace programs. This sample provides sufficient informational saturation, given the scope of the system and informants’ specialized roles (Bernard 2011).
Interviews
The interviews took approximately 1–2 h and were conducted in person or by telephone by two trained interviewers. Interviews were audio-recorded for transcription and semi-structured to ensure adequate coverage of targeted and emergent topics (Bernard 2011). Interviews provided background information, information about formal rules and informal practices (norms), and triangulating evidence regarding governance structures, processes, and outcomes. They also provided insight into key stakeholders’ reasoning and decision making. For example, questions about multi-actor cooperation asked when, why, and how particular stakeholder communicate and share important decisions—in addition to questions about enforcement and other design principles (see Appendix for sample questions).
Data preparation
We archived and numbered each line of the policy documents. Trained research assistants transcribed each interview verbatim, with line numbers and timestamps. The principal investigator (PI) resolved unknown terms and indiscernible statements.
Coding and analysis
Development of the coding system occurred iteratively, alongside the SRSG framework’s development. We followed conventions outlined by Ratajczyk et al. (2016). During Phase 1, the PIs used DeCaro et al.’s (2017, 2025b) conceptual definitions to create operational definitions for each design principle. We trained several advanced under/graduate students with domain knowledge as coders. The PIs and a senior coding assistant oversaw weekly coding meetings to revise the coding system. The team reached consensus on code definitions and examples before finalizing the data, using standardized codesheets.
During Phase 2, the PIs and senior coding assistant consolidated the coded entries for each design principle (i.e., capacity). We then descriptively summarized this information and compared the described capacities to the criteria listed in Tables 1–3. For example, when evaluating design principles for multi-actor cooperation (e.g., communication), we compared the partnership’s observed communication policies and practices with the criteria in Table 2. We rated each dimension on a five-point descriptive scale: - 2 (definitely lacks), -1 (may lack), 0 (not mentioned or mixed), +1 (may possess), +2 (definitely possesses). We assigned “definitely” scores (±2) when there was obvious (e.g., direct, explicit) and consistent evidence. We assigned “may” scores (±1) when the evidence was less obvious or strong, and “0” scores when a dimension was not mentioned or the evidence was mixed.
When formal policies (“rules on paper”) and informal institutional arrangements (“rules in use”) did not match, we coded the arrangements separately. Contradictory information was treated as directly informative. Thus, if interviewed participants reported different information or perspectives on an issue, then this information pinpointed areas of mixed institutional arrangements, poor communication, and/or deviation from formal policies. Coding formal and informal arrangements separately allowed us to investigate their potential interactions. We discuss especially important misalignments in the upcoming analyses.
We followed several recommendations to ensure coding reliability and validity (Ratajczyk et al. 2016, Seelandt 2018). First, the PIs have several years of domain-relevant experience. Second, the team collaborated to reach consensus. Finally, we provide our codesheets in open-access repositories to facilitate transparency and replicability.
RESULTS
As detailed in the following sections, we identified four interlocking system deficiencies. First, by selecting JCCE Office—a local administrative unit—as the primary (co)producer of community-governed greenspace, LMG and UK’s Extension Service failed to provision a viable solution for greenspace production (e.g., acquisition and management). This misfit severely crippled greenspace production, creating an unanticipated crisis. Second, the greenspace partners—primarily LMG, UK’s Extension Director, and JCCE Office—lacked sufficient, State-reinforced arrangements for multi-actor cooperation. This deficit decreased trust and collective problem solving, decreasing the partnership’s collective ATC to collaboratively resolve the aforementioned production crisis. Third, JCCE Office’s status as a subordinate administrative unit—without robust capacity for organizational self-governance—prevented it from altering its own capacities, or taking transformative action, to improve the situation. Finally, excessive reliance on informal arrangements created systemic confusion and failed to reinforce broad-scale polycentric self-governance or local community-level governance.
These institutional deficiencies were interdependent and robust, strengthening a maladaptive cycle of dysfunctional co-provision and co-production, which locked the stakeholders into a rigidity trap. Each deficiency undermined the system’s ATC, preventing it from correcting itself via transformation of the provision–production network.
We use descriptive tables with quantitative scores to summarize and explain these key findings (see referenced Tables and codesheets for details). We start with the focal archetype’s (JCCE Office’s) greenspace production to highlight its institutional misfit and the production crisis this created. We then report the features underlying JCCE Office’s diminished organizational self-governance, explaining its internal provisioning crisis. We conclude by reporting the design features of the partnership’s dysfunctional multi-actor cooperation, explaining the system’s collective provisioning crisis. The latter two analyses highlight how both severe constraint of the decentralized unit (JCCE Office) and poor collective problem solving prevented the stakeholders from (co)provisioning better solutions.
Greenspace production
The first dimension discussed is the (co)productive capacity of JCCE Office (Tables 4–5). This section highlights archetypal misfit and institutional deficits in greenspace production, in terms of both organization type and underlying ATCs. The section demonstrates the primary production failure(s) and crises that the governance system created and ultimately failed to respond to adaptively/transformatively.
Jefferson County Cooperative Extension Office is an inadequate community-greenspace producer for several reasons. First, Kentucky’s extension service is formally designed (authorized, required) to support agricultural research and outreach—not small neighborhood greenspace (KRS:§164.100, §164.125(2), MOA). Federal and state laws (Morrill Act:§2, Smith-Lever Act:§5, KRS:§164.110) forbid extension offices from purchasing, renting, or maintaining land/property for any purpose except Land Grant universities, offices, or agricultural research (Table 4; Codesheet 3):
[T]he land management part is definitely not a part of our [JCCE Office’s] mission, and...per KRS Statute, [we] are not allowed to own additional property other than property that our office building is physically located on. [W]e have had a couple private landowners from community gardens offer to sell us their land, which we cannot legally, um, do. (JCCE2: Horticultural Agent)
Because JCCE Office cannot acquire greenspaces long term, it relies on a disparate collection of informal land-use agreements and formal lease agreements. These agreements have widely varying tenure lengths (typically 1–5 yrs), terms, and user rights.
Second, JCCE Office’s inability to own community greenspace hindered its greenspace protection. For example, a senior LMG staff member said the following about the partnership’s flagship demonstration site, Parkland Community Garden:
[T]here was a grocery across the street, which closed long ago that Louisville Metro has recently purchased.... So you know, 10 years from now, that might be better served as part of that commercial district. ...We could terminate that lease if we had somebody who says, “Look, I’m gonna build a grocery store on this lot if you’ll sell it to me.” In that case, we would end the lease and, you know, try to help them find another location for that garden.
Some JCCE Office staff informally advocated for longer (5−10 yr) leases. However, this advocacy was largely unsuccessful. Communities struggled to commit to greenspace stewardship because of these short and informal (i.e., insecure) tenure rights (LG1, LOF1, JCCE2).
Third, JCCE Office was not formally authorized (or required) to transfer governance rights to local communities (Table 5; Codesheet 4). This institutional gap disempowered local communities, further eroding their stewardship and undermining the efficiency of site governance and maintenance (JCCE2).
Fourth, extension offices are not regulatory agencies and, therefore, lack formal mechanisms to regulate community members. The JCCE Office struggled to maintain regulatory oversight in the greenspaces:
[A]ll that we have is this Community Garden Agreement that exists but is not really enforceable because of the length of it and the disconnect between Cooperative Extension as the manager and Louisville Metro as the property owner and facilitator of the space. So that it makes—from a legal standpoint—it makes managing it kind of a very subjective situation, where you can wave a piece of paper and say, “this is what it says,” but if folks choose to not follow that, there’s no really good way to handle situations. (JCCE2: Horticultural Agent)
Interviews (JCCE1, JCCE2) indicated the Office had to wait for greenspace violations to become a law enforcement issue, or manage the sites itself. The JCCE Office decided to take control, further disempowering community-based governance.
Finally, $50,000 was not enough to administer the greenspace program, and the Office’s potential means to fund itself were deficient. Basic site upkeep cost approximately $60,000 annually and did not cover all sites (JCCE 2). The Office was formally authorized to collect “service fee compensations” (garden user fees), which generated approximately $10,000 during productive years (KRS 164:§655). However, this funding did not account for other expenses (e.g., water installation). Extension Districts are authorized to collected taxes to support their operations. However, JCCE was denied (KRS 164:§670). Therefore, JCCE Office’s greenspace program typically operated at a substantial deficit.
Summary
A particular type of organization (extension office) was given a critical role for which it was fundamentally poorly suited. Archetypal misalignment in underlying operational capacities (e.g., land acquisition, greenspace management, and funding), combined with misaligned in/formal arrangements, severely hindered JCCE Office’s ability to efficiently (co)produce community greenspaces. Weak reinforcement of community stewardship, combined with excessive external regulatory pressure from LMG and UK, ultimately compelled JCCE Office to take control of the greenspaces—increasing its operating costs. This strain prevented JCCE Office from acquiring new greenspaces, creating an unanticipated production crisis that perpetuated greenspace inequality the program was intended to fix.
Organizational self-governance
In this section, we report the focal decentralized unit’s capacity for organizational self-governance. If JCCE Office was self-governing, it could potentially alter its mission, organizational structure, rules, or norms to address its capacity limitations for greenspace (co)production (Tables 4–5). Organizational self-governance could also give JCCE Office bargaining power to reconfigure the partnership and/or program, transforming the provision–production network. Our analysis confirmed JCCE Office lacked organizational self-governance, consistent with a responsibility-heavy archetype (Table 6; Codesheet 1). The current analysis illustrates precisely how this critical aspect of State-reinforcement failed.
Constitutive and constitutional authority
Extension Offices typically have some authority to make decisions to govern themselves. However, JCCE Office is unique because it is a direct satellite of UK’s (i.e., Kentucky’s) Extension Service, the principal constitutional agent in this system (Smith-Lever Act:§2,§9, KRS 164:§125(2),625(1), Ordinance:§1,§4). The JCCE Office’s staff and local director are UK employees selected and supervised by UK’s Extension Director (MOA:§1(1,2), §4(4)). The JCCE Office, therefore, fundamentally lacks constitutive and constitutional decision-making authority (Table 6), undermining its organizational self-governance. It also lacks rule-making authority to govern itself. These restrictions severely limited JCCE Office’s ATC.
Administrative authority
As an administrative unit, JCCE Office is formally authorized to make administrative decisions to regulate its staff members, execute extension programs, and handle routine business operations (KRS:§164.125(2), §164.655(1)). However, the MOA among JCCE Office, LMG, and UK/UK’s Extension Director severely limited this authority (MOA:§1(2), §4(4)) (Table 6). In practice, LMG and UK/UK’s Extension Director intervened on JCCE Office’s internal affairs, further undermining its organizational self-governance. For example, UK’s Extension Director once intervened to resolve a dispute about chain of command (i.e., administrative authority) within JCCE Office triggered by an internal disagreement about administration of the greenspace program. Such oversight restricted the Office’s self-regulation and ability to adjust routine business operations to improve greenspace program performance.
Fiscal capacities
Finally, as previously noted JCCE Office received $350,000 annually for its general operations, with $50,000 allocated for the greenspace program. Our interviews with JCCE Office staff indicated that $350,000 was sufficient for the Office’s general operations. However, this money comes exclusively from external sources, greatly affecting the Office’s fiscal autonomy. Extension districts are typically authorized to collect taxes for local extension offices and programs (KRS:§164.665(8-17)), providing a degree of fiscal self-sufficiency, resilience, and autonomy. However, JCCE was denied this capacity (LOF1).
Several informants mentioned that threats to revoke JCCE Office’s annual stipend were used to compel the Office to comply with LMG and UK/UK Extension Director’s orders. This existential threat and JCCE Office’s lack of fiscal self-sufficiency severely constrained its constitutional and administrative decisions—further undermining its ability to operate independently and adaptively to address known problems.
Multi-actor cooperation
This section analyzes design principles underlying the partnership’s capacity for multi-actor cooperation (e.g., collective self-governance)—a critical source for institutional adaptation and transformation via collective problem solving (co-provisioning). Weak State-reinforcement and dysfunctional implementation of multi-actor cooperation was an important aspect of the system’s diminished ATC (Table 7; Codesheet 5).
Communication and shared decision making
Federal, state, and local laws governing Cooperative Extension give JCCE Office authority (and responsibility) to communicate with diverse stakeholders for agricultural outreach and development (e.g., Smith-Lever Act:§1-2, KRS 164:§125,§610, Ordinance:§31.331). However, these powers/duties are not specific to community greenspace, and the partners (e.g., MOA) did not formalize any such arrangements—making such activities voluntary.
Interviews revealed the partners did not routinely or comprehensively communicate about the program. They primarily communicated to address specific problems, like property maintenance (e.g., complaints, code violations), on an as-needed basis. Additionally, formal communication with gardeners and communities was largely unilateral: administrators (e.g., LMG, JCCE Office) communicated responsibilities (e.g., Garden Agreement rules) to gardeners, and they were expected to obey. Gardeners informally voiced their needs to JCCE Office staff, especially the horticulture agent. However, JCCE Office staff acknowledged that current communication was insufficient to address critical governance issues.
As previously noted, Extension Services in Kentucky are governed hierarchically. UK’s Extension Director is the principal decision-making agent, followed by counties, districts (e.g., Extension Board), local governments, and advisory councils (e.g., Smith-Lever Act:§1,9; KRS 164:§110, §625(2), §655(2,4)). These constitutional and administrative agents can make decisions collaboratively to govern extension services. However, the formal requirements (MOA) governing JCCE Office do not provide this authorization generally, or for community greenspace. And the partners did not create a formal multi-stakeholder decision-making body (e.g., greenspace committee) to share governance decisions. The partners rarely, if ever, convened collaborative decisions. Finally, when major governance issues arose, JCCE Office was often excluded or marginalized. The JCCE Office’s Director has no representation on the Extension District Board, or any other decision body. Requests by JCCE Office to change known problems with the Community Garden Agreement and the official MOA (to better reflect community-greenspace activities) were strictly denied.
Enforcement
Enforcement mechanisms within the partnership were complicated by weak formal arrangements. Direct enforcement via fines or lawsuit were weak because critical aspects of the partnership and community-greenspace program were governed by poorly specified, informal verbal agreements. Therefore, the stakeholders relied on indirect enforcement, like neighborhood complaints, code violations, financial threats, and gardener eviction (LF1-2, JCCE1-2). Interviews revealed evidence of poorly managed regulatory disputes within JCCE Office and among community members at particular sites. These disputes emerged from previously mentioned deficient communication and shared decision making, but also ill-defined sociopolitical boundaries, especially regarding roles and duties.
Sociopolitical and ecological boundaries
Ecological boundaries were well defined (Table 7). However, important roles, duties, and jurisdictions were informal and poorly defined. For example, interviews revealed disagreement (misconceptions) between LMG and JCCE Office about who governs and maintains the greenspaces—community members or Office staff. Ownership of some greenspaces was also unclear, because of poorly documented property titles/deeds. Finally, it was unclear who was responsible for water fees at some sites, LMG or JCCE Office.
Equity
Equity applies to multiple dimensions. As previously noted, existing policies governing JCCE Office do not ensure its or community-members’ equitable decision-making inclusion (see “Communication and shared decision making” above). However, the MOA governing JCCE Office’s (and the partnership’s) general operations do contain some cost- and labor-sharing provisions. Louisville Metro Government pays $350,000 annually, and UK covers salaries, equipment, training, and administrative supervision of JCCE Office. But these provisions do not pertain to the community-greenspace partnership.
Interviews with LMG and JCCE Office indicated the Office provides labor to regulate the gardeners and manage the greenspaces—yet lacks necessary funds and staff. Moreover, although some community members benefit from garden access, they must pay garden fees, and some greenspaces are not open to the entire community (JCCE1-2). Finally, communities were originally expected to govern and maintain the greenspaces but this failed—increasing JCCE Office’s operational costs. Altogether, JCCE Office carried the greatest burdens, while LMG and a few community members reaped the benefits.
Accountability
Accountability is a function of communication, shared decision making, and enforcement. The previously noted deficiencies in these dimensions (Table 7) translated into deficient accountability among key stakeholders. Horizontal and downward accountability were especially weak. The partners lacked robust methods to formally and informally hold each other accountable (horizontal accountability). Without formal rights to self-governance or equitable access, community members could not strictly hold higher agents (e.g., JCCE Office, LMG) accountable to these objectives (downward accountability). The JCCE Office was likewise unable to hold LMG, or UK’s Extension Director accountable to its needs (downward accountability) as the partnership’s de facto community-greenspace producer/provider.
However, this hierarchic system did authorize the higher administrative agents (e.g., LMG, UK’s Extension Director) to hold JCCE Office accountable (upward accountability). This disparity ensured that JCCE Office complied with higher administrators’ decisions, despite obvious operational deficiencies and institutional misalignments.
Summary
State (government) policies and actions did not robustly reinforce (e.g., authorize, require) effective multi-actor cooperation for this dilemma. And the stakeholders did not establish their own, informal mechanisms for effective cooperation. These deficiencies hindered collective problem solving, undermining the partnership’s ATC—preventing the partners from collectively devising (co-provisioning) better solutions to known production crises.
Results summary
Rather than create a polycentric system of SRSG to enable ATG based on principles of shared power (“power with”; Ostrom 1994), LMG and UK/UK’s Extension Director inadvertently created a multi-centered and increasingly hierarchic system, based on exerting “power over” subordinate actors and restricting their individual and collective innovation. Constitutional decision making, rule making, administrative, regulatory, and fiscal authority were monopolized by a few stakeholders. The focal decentralized unit (JCCE Office) lacked necessary capacities to efficiently produce greenspace (Tables 4–5), or govern itself (Table 6). Finally, multi-actor cooperation was not reinforced or practiced (Table 7). This rigid power system stifled the stakeholders’ independent and collective ATC—severely constraining institutional transformation. These conditions created a rigidity trap, eventually broken by LMG’s decision to abolish the partnership in 2024, after decades of mediocre performance.
DISCUSSION
Scholars argue that government-sponsored public–private partnerships can enable ATG and thereby improve the (co)provision (and production) of environmental public goods in response to social-ecological stressors (Folke et al. 2005, Chaffin et al. 2016a). However, maladaptive systems based on flawed concepts and/or implementation of State authority, de/centralization, polycentricity, self-governance, and resilience dominate many SESs (Andersson and Ostrom 2008, Ostrom 2010a,b, Clement et al. 2021). DeCaro et al. (2017, 2025b) argue this problem will persist until the fundamental building blocks—design principles, institutional archetypes, and governance network structures—associated with ATG become common knowledge and their mechanisms are adequately explained. This understanding requires rigorous diagnosis of institutional successes and failures (Baldwin et al. 2024).
We contributed to this goal by using the concept of State-reinforced self-governance (SRSG) (Sarker 2013) and DeCaro et al.’s (2017, 2025b) SRSG framework to analyze the design features underlying a case of failed polycentric ATG. The SRSG framework builds on Elinor and Vincent Ostrom’s prior work (e.g., Ostrom 1994, 2005a,b, 2010a,b), positing that governments can facilitate ATG by supporting dilemma stakeholders’ capacity for (co)production, independent action (organizational self-governance), and multi-actor cooperation (collective self-governance)—creating a polycentric, self-governing system for collective problem solving and institutional innovation (cf. Shivakumar 2005).
There are no simple solutions to complex social-ecological dilemmas (Ostrom et al. 2007). Key actors (institutional archetypes), rules, governance systems, and provision–production networks must be tailored the context, possessing adequate and appropriate (“fitting”) configurations of powers, duties, and operational resources (Ostrom 2010b, McGinnis 2011). The SRSG framework (DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b) argues that institutional fit emerges from collective self-organization and adaptive decision making, as stakeholders share information and collectively construct potential solutions (cf. Ostrom 1990, 2005a). SRSG is therefore about providing stakeholders capacities (e.g., authority, responsibility, operational resources) to engage in social-learning and co-provisioning (e.g., co-governance and design), to collectively identify effective means of (co)production for particular public goods/services and dilemmas within complex provision–production networks (cf. Oakerson 1999, Anderies et al. 2004, 2016).
The current case exhibited several interlocking misspecifications that can inform SRSG and ATG. First, government sponsors (e.g., LMG) selected an inappropriate institutional archetype—a local, administrative Extension Office that lacked essential greenspace production capacities—as the primary greenspace producer. This organizational misalignment, and misalignment of underlying capacities, created an unanticipated production crisis in greenspace acquisition and management.
Second, the government sponsors also (informally) assigned this local administrative unit (JCCE Office) primary responsibility for community greenspace (co)provision, but did not grant the Office constitutional (or administrative) decision-making and rule-making authority to govern itself or the greenspace program and its dilemma(s). The JCCE Office’s lack of organizational self-governance created an internal provisioning crisis, preventing it from devising its own solutions to known governance and greenspace management challenges.
Third, the public–private community-greenspace partnership lacked critical capacities for multi-actor cooperation (e.g., shared decision making, enforcement, equity), preventing the partners from collectively addressing known provision and production shortfalls. More specifically, the federal, state, and local laws (e.g., official MOA) did not sufficiently reinforce (authorize, require, or fund) the partners to collaborate, primarily because of archetypal misfit and excessive and disjointed informality. Critical aspects of the greenspace program were in disarray, making it unclear who was authorized or required to govern the community greenspaces, pay for water access, and regulate garden users.
Finally, the governance system was decentralized in structural form—with multiple centers of activity—but centralized in terms of decision-making power. Hierarchic decision structures and governance processes undermined the potential benefits of polycentric decentralization for collective provisioning (Andersson and Ostrom 2008). The system became fixated on principle-agent problems. Louisville Metro Government, UK’s Extension Director, and JCCE Office struggled to maintain basic compliance and, therefore, oriented increasingly toward regulatory actions rather than collaborative problem solving.
Therefore, we conclude that the Louisville case illustrates a failed attempt at SRSG. Such failures are commonplace in decentralization programs (DeCaro et al. 2025b). For example, with “deconcentration,” higher governments physically decentralize production operations to other units but retain centralized provisioning control (cf. Ribot et al. 2006). This approach has proliferated (e.g., Frimpong Boamah et al. 2025), because policy makers and scholars fail to distinguish design principles for (co)provisioning (constitutional authority) from (co)production (administrative/operational authority) (see Ostrom et al. 1993, Dardanelli 2021 for discussion). Our analysis demonstrates how to carefully distinguish these regimes.
Deconcentration undermines social-ecological resilience
By analyzing the current case in terms of failed SRSG, we provide insight into the long-standing debate regarding the optimality of various governance structures (e.g., centralized vs. decentralized) for delivery of public goods/services and social-ecological resilience, including “deconcentration” (see Oakerson 1999, Ostrom 2000).
In Louisville, the partnership attempted to enable resilient and efficient community-greenspace provision and production via a decentralized SRSG system, but ultimately created a system of deconcentrated (co)production, with hierarchic oversight. In short, LMG resorted to a commonly seen deconcentrated regime, contracting a service provider (JCCE Office), rather than empowering SRSG (cf. Oakerson 1999). When is deconcentration a viable solution to public good provision/production and resilience? What role does SRSG potentially play?
Prior research suggests that deconcentration is effective when (a) supervisory agents maintain effective regulatory control over the service provider, (b) performance quality is relatively easy and accurate to evaluate, and (c) a single, specific service is produced in a relatively predictable environment (Ostrom et al. 1993, Agrawal and Ribot 1999, Ostrom and Ostrom 2017). These conditions were not satisfied in Louisville. Louisville’s greenspace system was dynamic, exposed to many stressors, required diverse provision/production activities, was poorly regulated, and featured difficult-to-evaluate performance (e.g., community self-governance). According to the SRSG framework, deconcentrated systems cannot address these challenges well because key actors lack sufficient organizational self-governance and/or multi-actor cooperation to enable necessary transformation, or resilience (DeCaro et al. 2017, 2025b).
Another way to characterize this situation is in terms of engineered resilience vs. social-ecological resilience (Garmestani and Benson 2013). Like so many other failed decentralized programs, Louisville’s greenspace program was oriented toward engineered resilience—the ability to reliably deliver a narrow set of tightly calibrated goods/services—in a dilemma that required social-ecological resilience—the ability to adapt or transform structures, functions, and processes to deliver a wider array of goods/services in a complex and dynamic environment (Chaffin et al. 2016a, Clement et al. 2021).
Polycentric systems with multiple centers of organizational self-governance, constitutional decision-making authority, and robust mechanisms for multi-actor cooperation are thought to better enable such social-ecological resilience, because they facilitate co-provisioning and co-production by diverse stakeholders (Ostrom 2005a,b). Polycentric systems support “public entrepreneurship,” creating a political regime that encourages diverse stakeholders to independently and jointly innovate institutional arrangements (cf. Oakerson 1999). Such institutional innovation appears foundational to ATG. State-reinforced self-governance is a conceptualization of such polycentric, adaptive and transformative systems (DeCaro et al. 2025b).
Thus, the fundamental challenge when designing provision–production networks in ATG systems may be determining when to emphasize (a) (co)provisioning capacity and social-ecological resilience vs. (b) (co)production capacity and engineered resilience (e.g., Garmestani et al. 2019; cf. Oakerson 1999). Many decentralization programs appear to fall into a particular trap, failing to recognize that (co)provisioning capacity, although complex, can facilitate long-term (co)production capacity via enhanced social-ecological resilience (see Shivakumar 2005, Kemper et al. 2007, Andersson and Ostrom 2008 for review).
Future directions
The resilient governance of social-ecological dilemmas can be informed by additional lessons learned from our analysis of the Louisville case. Many factors affect institutional innovation and resilience (Ostrom 2005a, Kemper et al. 2007, Schifman et al. 2017, Stanford et al. 2022). Several illustrative factors stood out in the current case.
First, racial marginalization in environmental public good provision typically coincides with State oppression and neglect (e.g., Connolly and Anguelovksi 2021). State-reinforced self-governance implies reversal of oppression via community empowerment, in terms of increased community engagement and control of decision making (i.e., constitutional choice) (cf. Arnstein 1969). Louisville Metro Government has not embraced community empowerment in air pollution control (Sarr et al. 2021), policing (Department of Justice (DOJ) 2023), development (Storey et al. 2023), or greenspace—indicating a general orientation against SRSG. Research in other domains suggests that governments must regard community empowerment as a good in itself to enable robust forms of SRSG (e.g., Kemper et al. 2007).
Second, successful decentralization programs are often supported by complementary federal, state, and local policies (Craig et al. 2017, Bengston et al. 2004). For example, in a prominent greenspace case (Chicago’s NeighborSpace partnership), the state constitution included an environmental bill of rights establishing citizen rights to healthy ecological environments, and the city created a comprehensive greenspace plan and ordinances to support community greenspace. Additional supports for SRSG can come in such forms as removing legal barriers, providing funding, and coordinating specific policies (Cosens et al. 2017). However, specifying these elements is a fundamental challenge of ATG, and poorly understood. Such factors, therefore, warrant more research attention (DeCaro et al. 2025b).
Third, there are many potential institutional archetypes (e.g. organizations, configurations of ATC) for addressing environmental public good provision (Ostrom et al. 2007). We can learn some general strategies from the current case. Foster (2011) discusses several strategies, such as special districts (see also, Oakerson 1999). From a SRSG standpoint, special districts offer operational advantages fitting the “reinforced” (A+R+E+SS+) archetype. Districts typically possess constitutional and administrative powers to decide and implement programs for local development, may be governed collaboratively (depending on board composition and collective choice rules), and can collect taxes to fund programs/operations (cf. Hankerson 1957, Brooks 2008). Thus, like NPOs, special districts feature prominently in many State-reinforced ATG systems (e.g., Sarker 2013), including community greenspace (e.g., Foster 2011). Public–private partnership with NPOs illustrate another commonly used “reinforced” solution (e.g., DeCaro et al. 2025a). The critical issue for any governance regime is to ensure advantageously selected organizational archetypes, rules, partnerships, and governance networks for the self-organization of provision/production (cf. Oakerson 1999).
This discussion illustrates an important future research area. It is unclear what types and constellations of institutional archetypes, capacities, and network structures are particularly well-suited for particular kinds of social-ecological dilemmas and SESs (McGinnis and Ostrom 2014). We are only beginning to understand these contingencies in research and practice.
CONCLUSION
Elinor Ostrom (1998) remarked that civilizations would not exist if our ancestors had not learned to create systems of governance from trial-and-error experimentation. Ostrom (2005a) later concluded that humans create governance systems via basic knowledge of design principles for multi-actor cooperation (e.g., collective self-governance), which facilitate ATG via enhanced societal problem solving and social learning. Vincent Ostrom (1994) further introduced concepts of polycentricity, shared power, and interdependent but flexible provision–production networks as the basis for societal adaptation and transformation (Baldwin et al. 2024). Many policy makers and decision makers struggle to understand this institutional diversity, especially the State’s potential role(s) in facilitating ATG (cf. Oakerson 1999, Ostrom 2010a). The SRSG framework provides additional leverage over this problem in two ways. First, it supplies additional methods to identify design principles that embody State involvement in self-governance. Second, it provides methods to analyze archetypal configurations of ATCs associated with particular types of organizations and governance network structures. This approach enables analysts to understand which State actions and institutional design features facilitate (or hinder) polycentric forms of ATG. We applied this perspective to the current study, seeking to illuminate institutional foundations of State-reinforced ATG by examining a failed decentralization program. We discovered that institutional misfit in the form of poor-fitting organizations, and archetypal capacities for (co)production, as well as deficient provisions for organizational self-governance and multi-actor cooperation severely undermine the ATC of a governance system. These deficiencies prevent dilemma stakeholders from independently and jointly provisioning better solutions to complex production problems.
RESPONSES TO THIS ARTICLE
Responses to this article are invited. If accepted for publication, your response will be hyperlinked to the article. To submit a response, follow this link. To read responses already accepted, follow this link.
AUTHOR CONTRIBUTIONS
DD (senior PI) designed and supervised the study and secured funding. DD created the research protocol (e.g., interview questions) and coding methodology with collaboration of MAR, GAA, and EFB. MAR conducted interviews. DD, MAR, GAA, EFB analyzed the data. MAR was a senior coding assistant. DD drafted the initial manuscript with revisions by MAR, GAA, and EFB.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
This work was supported by the National Socio-Environmental Synthesis Center (SESYNC) under funding received from the National Science Foundation DBI-1639145. Neither SESYNC nor NSF was involved in the study design, data collection, analysis or interpretation of data, decision to submit this paper for publication, or manuscript draft. Any opinions, findings, and conclusions or recommendations expressed in this material are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily reflect the views of SESYNC or NSF.
We wish to acknowledge the following research assistants: Phoenix Combs, Willow Dietsch, Michelle Goderwis, Kaitlyn Hite, Anna Kelecy, Chris Wales, Aubrey Vittitow, Sydney Wright.
Use of Artificial Intelligence (AI) and AI-assisted Tools
n/a
DATA AVAILABILITY
Codes derived from these data and anonymized interview data that support the findings of this study are openly available in OSF (https://osf.io/7t4am/?view_only=2d716009d89b4282b9758ee3ebac3f39). Ethical approval for this research study was granted by the principal investigator’s University human subjects institutional review board (IRB 17.0723, 19.0588). All interviewers and data analysts were certified for adherence to ethical standards to protect human data. The interviewees participated voluntarily, with informed consent.
LITERATURE CITED
Acs, G., R. Pendall, M. Trekson, and A. Khare. 2017. The cost of segregation: national trends and the case of Chicago, 1990–2010. Urban Institute, Washington, D.C., USA. https://www.urban.org/research/publication/cost-segregation
Agrawal, A., and J. C. Ribot. 1999. Accountability in decentralization: a framework with South Asian and West African cases. Journal of Developing Areas 33:473-502.
Anderies, J. M., M. A. Janssen, and E. Ostrom. 2004. A framework to analyze the robustness of social-ecological systems from an institutional perspective. Ecology and Society 9(1):18. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-00610-090118
Anderies, J. M., M. A. Janssen, and E. Schlager. 2016. Institutions and the performance of coupled infrastructure systems. International Journal of the Commons 10(2):495-516. https://doi.org/10.18352/ijc.651
Anderson, E. C., M. H. Egerer, N. Fouch, M. Clarke, and M. J. Davidson. 2019. Comparing community garden typologies of Baltimore, Chicago, and New York City (USA) to understand potential implications for socio-ecological services. Urban Ecosystems 22:671-681. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11252-019-00855-9
Andersson, K. P., and E. Ostrom. 2008. Analyzing decentralized resource regimes from a polycentric perspective. Policy Sciences 41:71-93. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11077-007-9055-6
Arnstein, S. R. 1969. A ladder of citizen participation. Journal of the American Institute of Planners 35:216-224. https://doi.org/10.1080/01944366908977225
Baldwin, E., A. Thiel, M. McGinnis, and E. Kellner. 2024. Empirical research on polycentric governance: critical gaps and a framework for studying long-term change. Policy Studies Journal 52(2):319-348. https://doi.org/10.1111/psj.12518
Barnes, M. L., Ö. Bodin, A. M. Guerrero, R. R. J. McAllister, S. M. Alexander, and G. Robins. 2017. The social structural foundations of adaptation and transformation in social-ecological systems. Ecology and Society 22(4):16. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-09769-220416
Bengston, D. N., J. O. Fletcher, and K. C. Nelson. 2004. Public policies for managing urban growth and protecting open space: policy instruments and lessons learned in the United States. Landscape and Urban Planning 69:271-286. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landurbplan.2003.08.007
Bernard, R. H. 2011. Interviewing I: unstructured and semistructured. Pages 156-186 in R. H. Bernard, editor. Research methods in anthropology: qualitative and quantitative approaches. AltaMira Press, Letchworth Garden City, UK.
Brooks, L. 2008. Volunteering to be taxed: business improvement districts and the extra-governmental provision of public safety. Journal of Public Economics 92(1-2):388-406. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpubeco.2007.07.002
Bullard, R. D., and G. S. Johnson. 2000. Environmentalism and public policy: environmental justice: grassroots activism and its impact on public policy decision making. Journal of Social Issues 56:555-578. https://doi.org/10.1111/0022-4537.00184
Cahn, A. L., and P. Z. Segal. 2016. You can’t common what you can’t see: towards a restorative polycentrism in the governance of our cities. Fordham Urban Law Journal 43:195-245. https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/ulj/vol43/iss2/1/
Carper, W. B. and W. E. Snizek. 1980. The nature and types of organizational taxonomies: an overview. Academy of Management Review 5(1):65-75. https://doi.org/10.5465/amr.1980.4288887
Chaffin, B. C., A. S. Garmestani, L. H. Gunderson, M. H. Benson, D. G. Angeler, C. A. (T.) Arnold, B. Cosens, R. K. Craig, J. B. Ruhl, and C. R. Allen. 2016a. Transformative environmental governance. Annual Review of Environmental Resources 41:399-423. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-environ-110615-085817
Chaffin, B. C., H. Gosnell, and B. A. Cosens. 2014. A decade of adaptive governance scholarship: synthesis and future directions. Ecology and Society 19(3):56. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-06824-190356
Chaffin, B. C., W. D. Shuster, A. S. Garmestani, B. Furio, S. L. Albro, M. Gardiner, L. Albro, M. Gardiner, M. Spring, and O. O. Green. 2016b. A tale of two rain gardens: barriers and bridges to adaptive management of urban stormwater in Cleveland, Ohio. Journal of Environmental Management 183:431-441. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jenvman.2016.06.025
Clement, S., J. Jozaei, M. Mitchell, C. R. Allen, and A. S. Garmestani. 2021. How resilience is framed matters for governance of coastal social-ecological systems. Environmental Policy and Governance 34:65-76. https://doi.org/10.1002/eet.2056
Colding, J., S. Barthel, P. Bendt, R. Snep, W. van der Knaap, and H. Ernstson. 2013. Urban green commons: insights on urban common property systems. Global Environmental Change 23:1039-1051. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2013.05.006
Connolly, J. J. T., and I. Anguelovski. 2021. Three histories of greening and whiteness in American cities. Frontiers in Ecology and Evolution 9:621783. https://doi.org/10.3389/fevo.2021.621783
Cooperative Extension Service (CES). 2024. Overview of Kentucky Cooperative Extension. Cooperative Extension Service Manuals, Kentucky CES, Lexington, Kentucky, USA. https://ces-manuals.ca.uky.edu/overview-kentucky-cooperative-extension.
Cosens, B. A., R. K. Craig, S. L. Hirsch, C. A. (T.) Arnold, M. H. Benson, D. A. DeCaro, A. S. Garmestani, H. Gosnell, J. Ruhl, and E. Schlager. 2017. The role of law in adaptive governance. Ecology and Society 22(1):30. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-08731-220130
Craig, R. K., A. S. Garmestani, R. Allen, C. A. Arnold, H. Birgé, D. A. DeCaro, A. K. Fremier, H. Gosnell, and E. Schlager. 2017. Balancing stability and flexibility in adaptive governance: an analysis of tools available in U.S. environmental law. Ecology and Society 22(2):3. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-08983-220203
Crawford, S., and E. Ostrom. 2005. A grammar of institutions. Pages 137-174 in E. Ostrom, editor. Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA. https://doi.org/10.2307/2082975
Croutcher, D. 2017. The west end: a tale of two cities. Louisville Magazine (March):24-29.
Cumming, G. S. 2018. A review of social dilemmas and social-ecological traps in conservation and natural resource management. Conservation Letters 11(1):1-15. https://doi.org/10.1111/conl.12376
Cumming, G. S., G. Epstein, J. M Anderies, C. I. Apetrei, J. Baggio, Ö. Bodin, S. Chawla, H. S. Clements, M. Cox, L. Egli, G. G. Gurney, M. Lubell, N. Magliocca, T. H. Morrison, B. Müller, R. Seppelt, M. Schlüter, H. Unnikrishnan, S. Villamayor-Tomas, and C. M. Weible. 2020. Advancing understanding of natural resource governance: a post-Ostrom research agenda. Current Opinion in Environmental Sustainability 44:26-34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cosust.2020.02.005
Dardanelli, P. 2021. Conceptualizing and measuring decentralization. Pages 9-26 in I. Lago, editor. Handbook on decentralization, devolution and the State. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, Massachusetts, USA. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781839103285.00008
DeCaro, D. A., B. C. Chaffin, E. Schlager, A. S. Garmestani, and J. B. Ruhl. 2017. Legal and institutional foundations of adaptive environmental governance. Ecology and Society 22(1):32. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-09036-220132
DeCaro, D. A., E. Frimpong Boamah, M. A. Rudolph, and G. A. Adusei. 2025a. State-reinforced co-provision of community-governed greenspace in racially marginalized neighborhoods: lessons from Chicago’s innovative NeighborSpace land trust and partnership. Ecology and Society 30(2):2. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-15783-300202
DeCaro, D. A., M. A. Janssen, and A. Lee. 2021. Motivational foundations of communication, voluntary cooperation, and self-governance in a common-pool resource dilemma. Current Research in Ecological and Social Psychology 2:100016. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.cresp.2021.100016
DeCaro, D. A., E. Schlager, and E. Frimpong Boamah. 2025b. The state-reinforced self-governance framework: conceptualizing and diagnosing legal and other institutional foundations of adaptive and transformative environmental governance. Ecology and Society 30(2):1. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-15567-300201
Department of Economic Growth and Innovation (DEGI). 2013. Community gardens in Louisville: a start-up guide. DEGI, Louisville, Kentucky, USA. https://louisville.edu/cepm/pdf-files/community-gardens-in-louisville-a-start-up-guide/view
Department of Justice (DOJ). 2023. Agreement in principle among the United States and Louisville/Jefferson County Metro Government and the Louisville Metro Police Department. https://www.justice.gov/opa/press-release/file/1573016/dl
Diekmann, L., R. Bennaton, J. Schweiger, and C. Smith. 2017. Involving Extension in urban food systems: an example from California. Journal of Human Sciences and Extension 5(2):7. https://doi.org/10.54718/ZLAU1939
Engle, N. L. 2011. Adaptive capacity and its assessment. Global Environmental Change 21(2):647-656. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2011.01.019
Epstein, G. 2017. Local rulemaking, enforcement and compliance in state-owned forest commons. Ecological Economics 131:312-321. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.09.012
Folke, C., T. Hahn, P. Olsson, and J. Norberg. 2005. Adaptive governance of social-ecological systems. Annual Review of Environment and Resources 30:441-473. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev.energy.30.050504.144511
Foster, S. R. 2011. Collective action and the urban commons. Notre Dame Law Review 87:57. https://ir.lawnet.fordham.edu/faculty_scholarship/190
Foster, S. R., and C. Iaione. 2016. The city as a commons. Yale Law and Policy Review 34:282-349. http://hdl.handle.net/20.500.13051/17250
Franz, N. K., and L. Townson. 2008. The nature of complex organizations: the case of cooperative extension. New Directions for Evaluation 120:5-14. https://doi.org/10.1002/ev.272
Frimpong Boamah, E., T. Yeboah, K. Adamu, F. Yin, E. Yeleliere, T. P. Appai, and K. O. Twum. 2025. State-mandated decentralized irrigation reforms: (re)thinking Africa’s irrigation commons using the state-reinforced self-governance framework. Ecology and Society: in press.
Garmestani, A. S., and M. H. Benson. 2013. A framework for resilience-based governance of social-ecological systems. Ecology and Society 18(1):9. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-05180-180109
Garmestani, A., J. B. Ruhl, B. C. Chaffin, R. K. Craig, H. F. M. W. van Rijswick, D. G. Angeler, C. Folke, L. Gunderson, D. Twidwell, and C. R. Allen. 2019. Untapped capacity for resilience in environmental law. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 116(40):19899-19904. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.1906247116
Gilderbloom, J. I., W. L. Meares, and W. Riggs. 2016. How brownfield sites kill places and people: an examination of neighborhood housing values, foreclosures, and lifespan. Journal of Urbanism: International Research on Placemaking and Urban Sustainability 9(1):1-18. https://doi.org/10.1080/17549175.2014.905488
Gotham, K. F. 2000. Racialization and the state: the Housing Act of 1934 and the creation of the Federal Housing Administration. Sociological Perspectives 43(2):291-317. https://doi.org/10.2307/1389798
Green, O. O., A. S. Garmestani, S. Albro, N. C. Ban, A. Berland, C. E. Burkman, M. M. Gardiner, L. Gunderson, M. E. Hopton, M. L. Schoon, and W. D. Shuster. 2016. Adaptive governance to promote ecosystem services in urban green spaces. Urban Ecosystems 19:77-93. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11252-015-0476-2
Grimm, N. B., S. H. Faeth, N. E. Golubiewski, C. L. Redman, J. Wu, X. Bai, and J. M. Briggs. 2008. Global change and the ecology of cities. Science 319(5864):756-760. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.1150195
Hankerson, J. A. 1957. Special governmental districts. Texas Law Review 35:1004-1010. https://heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.journals/tlr35&i=1030
Hosseinioon, S. 2019. Urban resilience and informality: effects of formalisation in Golestan, Iran. Pages 111-127 in G. Brunetta, O. Caldarice, N. Tollin, M. Rosas-Casals, and J. Morató, editors, Urban resilience for risk and adaptation governance, resilient cities. Springer, Cham, Switzerland. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-76944-8_8
Jaffe, R., and M. Koster. 2019. The myth of formality in the Global North: informality-as-innovation in Dutch Governance. International Journal of Urban Regional Research 43:563-568. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2427.12706
Kemper, K. E., W. Blomquist, and A. Dinar. 2007. River basin management at the lowest appropriate level: when and why does it (not) work in practice? Pages 3-15 in K. E. Kemper, A. Dinar, and W. Blomquist, editors. Integrated river basin management through decentralization. Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg, Germany. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-540-28355-3_1
Kirshbaum, P. R. 2000. Making policy in a crowded world: steps beyond the physical garden. Community Greening Review 10:2-11.
Lane, M. J. 1980. Legal handbook for nonprofit organizations. AMACOM, New York, New York, USA.
Marshall, A. 2017. Louisville’s dividing lines: the results of redlining in the city. Louisville Magazine 54-61.
Mattijssen, T., B. Arjen, E. B. Elands, and A. Bas. 2018. The ‘green’ and ‘self’ in green self-governance—a study of 264 green space initiatives by citizens. Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 20(1):96-113. https://doi.org/10.1080/1523908X.2017.1322945
Mattingly, J. 2021. How racism is built into Louisville’s infrastructure. Louisville Political Review, October 2021. https://loupolitical.org/2021/10/01/how-racism-is-built-into-louisvilles-infrastructure/
McGinnis, M. D. 2011. Networks of adjacent action situations in polycentric governance. Policy Studies Journal 39(1):51-78. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1541-0072.2010.00396.x
McGinnis, M. D. 2017. The IAD Framework in action: understanding the source of the design principles in Elinor Ostrom’s Governing the Commons. Pages 87-108 in D. H. Cole and M. D. McGinnis, editors. Elinor Ostrom and the Bloomington school of political economy: volume 3, a framework for policy analysis. Lexington Books, Lanham, Maryland, USA. https://mcginnis.pages.iu.edu/McG-IAD%20applied%20book%20version.pdf
McGinnis, M. D., and E. Ostrom. 2014. Social-ecological system framework: initial changes and continuing challenges. Ecology and Society 19(2):30. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-06387-190230
Morgan, D. R. and R. E. England. 1988. The two faces of privatization. Public Administration Review 48(6):979-987. https://doi.org/10.2307/976994
Nardone, A., K. E. Rudolph, R. Morello-Frosch, and J. A. Casey. 2021. Redlines and greenspace: the relationship between historical redlining and 2010 greenspace across the United States. Environmental Health Perspectives 129(1):017006. https://doi.org/10.1289/EHP7495
Nelson, M. C. 2017. Nobody’s home: a look at the West End’s vacant properties. Louisville Magazine. https://archive.louisville.com/content/nobodys-home
Oakerson, R. J. 1999. Governing local public economies: creating the civic metropolis. Institute for Contemporary Studies (ICS) Press, San Francisco, California, USA.
Ostrom, E. 1990. Governing the commons: evolution of institutions for collective action. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511807763
Ostrom, E. 1992. The rudiments of a theory of the origins, survival, and performance of common-property institutions. Pages 293-318 in D. W. Bromley, editor. Making the commons work: theory, practice, and policy. Institute for Contemporary Studies Press, San Franciso, California, USA.
Ostrom, E. 1996. Crossing the great divide: coproduction, synergy, and development. World Development 24:1073-1087. https://doi.org/10.1016/0305-750X(96)00023-X
Ostrom, E. 1998. A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action: presidential address, American Political Science Association, 1997. American Political Science Review 92:1-22. https://doi.org/10.2307/2585925
Ostrom, E. 2000. The danger of self-evident truths. PS: Political Science and Politics 33:33-46. https://doi.org/10.2307/420774
Ostrom, E. 2005a. Robust resource governance in polycentric institutions. Pages 255-288 in E. Ostrom, editor. Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA. https://doi.org/10.2307/j.ctt7s7wm.13
Ostrom, E. 2005b. Zooming in and linking action situations. Pages 33-68 in E. Ostrom, editor. Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA. https://doi.org/10.2307/j.ctt7s7wm.6
Ostrom, E. 2010a. Beyond markets and states: polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review 100(3):641-672. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.100.3.641
Ostrom, E. 2010b. Polycentric systems for coping with collective action and global environmental change. Global Environmental Change 20(3):550-557. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2010.07.004
Ostrom, E., and S. Crawford. 2005. Classifying rules. Pages 186-187 in E. Ostrom, editor. Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA.
Ostrom, E., M. A. Janssen, and J. M. Anderies. 2007. Going beyond panaceas. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 104(39):15176-15178. https://doi.org/10.1073/pnas.0701886104
Ostrom, E., and V. Ostrom. 2017. Public economy organization and service delivery. Pages 111-146 in D. H. Cole and M. D. McGinnis, editors. Elinor Ostrom and the Bloomington school of political economy: volume 3, a framework for policy analysis. Lexington Books, Lanham, Maryland, USA.
Ostrom E., L. Schroeder, and S. Wynne. 1993. Decentralized institutional arrangements. Pages 163-176 in E. Ostrom, S. Schroeder, and S. Wynne, editors. Institutional incentives and sustainable development: infrastructure policies in perspective. Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado, USA.
Ostrom, V. 1980. Hobbes, covenant, and constitution. Publius 10:83-100. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordjournals.pubjof.a037335
Ostrom, V. 1994. The meaning of American federalism: constituting a self-governing society. Institute for Contemporary Studies (ICS) Press, San Francisco, California, USA.
Parks and People Foundation (PPF). 2000. Neighborhood open space management: a report of greening strategies in Baltimore and six other cities. Parks and People Foundation, Baltimore, Maryland, USA. https://www.csu.edu/cerc/documents/NeighborhoodOpenSpaceManagement-AReportonGreeningStrategiesinBaltimoreandSixOtherCitiesSprin.pdf
Pritchett, W. E. 2003. The public menace of blight: urban renewal and the private uses of eminent domain. Yale Law Policy Review 21:1-52. https://www.jstor.org/stable/i40008649
Ratajczyk, E., U. Brady, J. A. Baggio, A. J. Barnett, I. Perez-Ibarra, N. Rollins, C. Rubiños, H. C. Shin, D. J. Yu, R. Aggarwal, J. M. Anderies, and M. A. Janssen. 2016. Challenges and opportunities in coding the commons: problems, procedures, and potential solutions in large-N comparative case studies. International Journal of the Commons 10(2):440-466. https://doi.org/10.18352/ijc.652
Reynolds, K. A. 2011. Expanding technical assistance for urban agriculture: best practices for extension services in California and beyond. Journal of Agricultural Food Systems and Community Development 1(3):1-20. https://doi.org/10.5304/jafscd.2011.013.013
Ribot, J. C., A. Agrawal, and A. M. Larson. 2006. Recentralizing while decentralizing: how national governments reappropriate forest resources. World Development 34:1864-1886. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2005.11.020
Rigolon, A., M. Browning, and V. Jennings. 2018a. Inequities in the quality of urban park systems: an environmental justice investigation of cities in the United States. Landscape and Urban Planning 178:156-169. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landurbplan.2018.05.026
Rigolon, A., M. Browning, K. Lee, and S. Shin. 2018b. Access to urban green space in cities of the Global South: a systematic literature review. Urban Science 2:67. https://doi.org/10.3390/urbansci2030067
Ruemenapp, M. A. 2017. America’s changing urban landscape: positioning Extension for success. Journal of Human Sciences and Extension 5(2):6-21. https://doi.org/10.54718/SHDR3948
Sarker, A. 2013. The role of state-reinforced self-governance in averting the tragedy of the irrigation commons in Japan. Public Administration 91(3):727-743. https://doi.org/10.1111/padm.12011
Sarr, S., B. Hayes, and D. A. DeCaro. 2021. Applying Ostrom’s institutional analysis and development framework, and design principles for co-production to pollution management in Louisville’s Rubbertown, Kentucky. Land Use Policy 104:105383. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landusepol.2021.105383
Schifman, L. A., D. L. Herrmann, W. D. Shuster, A. Ossola, A. S. Garmestani, and M. E. Hopton. 2017. Situating green infrastructure in context: a framework for adaptive socio‐hydrology in cities. Water Resources Research 53:10139-10154. https://doi.org/10.1002/2017WR020926
Schukoske, J. E. 2000. Community development through gardening: state and local policies transforming urban open space. New York University Journal of Legislation and Public Policy 3:351-392. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1426079
Seelandt, J. 2018. Quality control: assessing reliability and validity. Pages 227-244 in E. Brauner, M. Boos, and M. Kolbe, editors. The Cambridge handbook of group interaction analysis. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781316286302.013
Sharifi, A. 2016. From garden city to eco-urbanism: the quest for sustainable neighborhood development. Sustainable Cities and Society 20:1-16. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.scs.2015.09.002
Shivakumar, S. J. 2005. The constitution of development: crafting capabilities for self-governance. Palgrave Macmillan, London, UK.
Siders, A. R. 2019. Adaptive capacity to climate change: a synthesis of concepts, methods, and findings in a fragmented field. WIREs Climate Change 10:e573. https://doi.org/10.1002/wcc.573
Singh, S., A. Martins, and O. Tefera. 2022. Nonprofit organisational resilience: proposing a conceptual adaptive capacity framework. Acta Commercii 22(1):a1077. https://doi.org/10.4102/ac.v22i1.1077
Smiley, K.T., W. Rushing, and M. Scott. 2014. Behind a bicycling boom: governance, cultural change and place character in Memphis, Tennessee. Urban Studies 53:193-209. https://doi.org/10.1177/0042098014556590
Smith, C. M., and H. E. Kurtz. 2003. Community gardens and politics of scale in New York City. Geographical Review 93:193-212. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1931-0846.2003.tb00029.x
Stanford, H. R., G. E. Garrard, H. Kirk, and J. Hurley. 2022. A social-ecological framework for identifying and governing informal greenspaces in cities. Landscape and Urban Planning 221:104378. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.landurbplan.2022.104378
Storey, A., D. Johnson, V. Clemens, A. Smith, D. A. DeCaro, and L. Heberle. 2023. Becoming resilient: exploring community well-being through politicized participation in Louisville, KY. Pages 149-169 in M.R. Islam and P. Kraeger, editors. Social (in)equality, community well-being, and quality of life. Edward Elgar Publishing, Northampton, Massachusetts, USA. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781035312450.00013
Sun, Y., S. Saha, H. Tost, X. Kong, and C. Xu. 2022. Literature review reveals a global access inequity to urban green spaces. Sustainability 14:1062. https://doi.org/10.3390/su14031062
Tarko V., E. Schlager E, and M. Lutter. 2019. The Faustian bargain. Pages 219-236 in A. Thiel, W. A. Blomquist, and D. E. Garrick, editors. Governing complexity: analyzing and applying polycentricity. Cambridge University Press, New York, New York, USA. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108325721.011
Trust for Public Land. 2023. 2023 ParkScore: Louisville/Jefferson, Kentucky. Trust for Public Land, San Francisco, California, USA. https://parkserve.tpl.org/downloads/historic/2023_ParkScoreRank.pdf
U.S. Census Bureau. 2021. QuickFacts: Chicago city, Illinois. U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, D.C., USA.
Vacant and Abandoned Property Administration (VPPA). 2018. Property inventory (11-30-2017). Vacant and Abandoned Property Administration, Louisville, Kentucky, USA. https://louisvilleky.gov/government/vacant-public-property-administration/purchase-vacant-property-metro
Voorberg, W. H, V. J. J. M. Bekkers, and L. G. Tummers. 2014. A systematic review of co-creation and co-production: embarking on the social innovation journey. Public Management Review 17(9):1333-1357. https://doi.org/10.1080/14719037.2014.930505
Wang, D., and Y. Liang. 2024. Environmental decentralization and urban green space provision: based on the multidimensional perspective of decentralization. Environment, Development and Sustainability:1-32. https://doi.org/10.1007/s10668-023-04393-5
Fig. 1

Fig. 1. Equitable greenspace: sub-dilemma(s) and action situations. Note: Common-pool resource dilemma (CPR); public good dilemma (PG); focal dilemma (*).

Fig. 2

Fig. 2. Governance network: community-greenspace partnership system. Note: B - Board of Directors; DC - district council person; g - gardener; JD - Jefferson County Director of Extension; LB - land bank authority; LF - Louisville Forward; LMG - Louisville metro government; M - mayor; MSD - metropolitan sewer district; O - office; p - public (representative of public interest/organization); PR - private land owner; SF - staff; UKD - University of Kentucky Director of Extension; ★ - focal actor, JCCE Office; * - focal action situation (co-provision/co-production of Louisville’s city-wide community greenspace program. Solid lines - strong connection; dotted lines - weak connection.

Fig. 3

Fig. 3. Race and poverty within 0.8-km (0.5-mile) radius of the greenspaces.

Table 1
Table 1. Community greenspace production activities (operational capacities).
Activity/Operational Capacity | Description | |
Land Acquisition | ||
Coordinate | Coordinate land inventory and exchange with local governments and private owners; communicate and share land acquisition/transfer decisions. | |
Acquire | Acquire (e.g., own, hold easement, lease) eligible land (i.e., small openspace/greenspace). | |
Protect | Ensure long-term tenure and usage rights for greenspace; protect against development and market speculation. | |
Insure (Property) | Insure the property against loss/damage. | |
Financial Efficiency | Obtain sufficient/efficient funding and financial transactions for land acquisition, tenure, and protection. Pay debts and property taxes. | |
Pollution Remediation | Test and remediate soil pollution/hazards. | |
Land Management | ||
Coordinate | Coordinate with local communities, organizations, and greenspace stewards; communicate and share decisions regarding siting and management. | |
Manage | Perform routine maintenance, upkeep, development, as well as administrative (operational) decision making and rule making. | |
Transfer Rights | Authorize stewards to manage/use the greenspace. | |
Transfer Responsibility | Require stewards to manage/use the greenspace. | |
Insure (Liability) | Insure for liability (e.g., legal, bodily). | |
Regulate | Monitor stewards; enforce rules and obligations. | |
Financial Viability/Efficiency | Sufficient and efficient funding and financial transactions for land/greenspace management, upkeep, development. | |
Provide Services | Provide financial and in-kind support; labor, human capital (expertise), education, information, and civic training. | |
Provide Water | Provide affordable/efficient access to water; install infrastructure. | |
Table 2
Table 2. Institutional design principles (adaptive and transformative capacities). Source: DeCaro et al. (2025b).
Principle/Capacity | Description | |
Multi-actor Cooperation | ||
Communication | Sufficient communication among stakeholders to support coordination and mutual understanding of the dilemma and each other (e.g., roles, goals, characteristics, capacities and constraints). | |
Shared Decision Making | Key stakeholders collaboratively and meaningfully participate in relevant decisions. Stakeholders are empowered to collectively determine critical goals, institutional designs, and governance processes. | |
Enforcement | Effective methods to compel cooperation with rules and social contracts, whether in/formal, internal/external. Graduated sanctions (escalating punishments). Restorative justice (conflict resolution involving multi-lateral communication, deliberation, and education). | |
Well-Defined Boundaries | Ecological boundaries (e.g., geospatial, biophysical properties/dynamics) of the dilemma are clearly defined, understood, and known to the key stakeholders. Sociopolitical boundaries (e.g., actors; actor roles, jurisdictions, and capacities) are well understood and known by key stakeholders. | |
Equity | Costs/benefits of governing the dilemma are shared equitably. | |
Accountability | Actors and collective action processes are held accountable to superior authorities (upward accountability) (Ribot et al. 2006), peers (horizontal accountability) (Ostrom 1990, 2010a), and/or constituents (downward accountability) (Ribot et al. 2006). A function of communication, shared decision making, and enforcement. | |
State-Reinforcement | ||
Authority | A) Authorization to make decisions (“decision-making authority”) to govern oneself and relevant aspects of the dilemma. Includes constitutional authority to decide fundamental rules and structures, and administrative authority to decide business affairs and operations. B) Authorization to conduct necessary functions (“operational authority”). | |
Responsibility | Requirements to perform particular functions. | |
Operational Resources | External resources (e.g., funding, equipment, facilities) and sources or mechanisms for self-sufficiency to acquire necessary resources to conduct vital functions. Balance influences fiscal autonomy, which influences de facto independence and authority. | |
Flexibility/Stability | Flexibility to change core institutional structures (e.g., constitutional makeup, rules), operations, and/or functions. Examples: decision authority, policy sunsets, general standards (e.g., legal ceilings/floors). Stability to ensure advantageous institutional characteristics resist change to enable beneficial predictability and long-term goals (e.g., decision constraints, fixed rules). Balance affects relative flexibility. | |
Table 3
Table 3. Organizational capacities for self-governance. Note: DM (decision making); RM (rule making).
Principle/Capacity | Description | ||||||||
Constitutive | Define and create (incorporate) organization and fundamental organizational structure (e.g., roles, committees), as well as mission, rules, and decisions (see also, Constitutional Decision Making/Rule Making) | ||||||||
Constitutional Decision Making/Rule Making | Make fundamental decisions and rules (social contracts: e.g., bylaws) for own governance. | ||||||||
Administrative Decision Making/Rule Making | Make routine decisions and rules (e.g., best practices) for basic operations in regular implementation of core functions. | ||||||||
Regulation | Monitor own (e.g., collective, organizational, member) actions, enforce rules, punish, and remediate. | ||||||||
Fiscal Viability | Fund and financially support itself, including external sources and internal/inherent sources of self-sufficiency. | ||||||||
Table 4
Table 4. Jefferson County Cooperative Extension (JCCE) Office’s operational (production) capacities: land acquisition. Note: AUTH - authority; F - formal; I - informal; LMG - Louisville metro government; RESP - responsibility; UK - University of Kentucky. Five-point scale: from -2 (definitely lacks) to 2 (definitely possesses).
Principle (capacity) | Description | AUTH | RESP | ||||||
F | I | F | I | ||||||
Coordinate | Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office de facto, informal coordinator for the program’s greenspace acquisition (informal responsibility). Federal, state, and local law governing Extension authorize (and require) land acquisition for core operations (e.g., research, outreach), but not community greenspace. LMG and UK informally authorized JCCE Office to serve as coordinator, in a limited administrative role. | -2 | 0 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Acquire | Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office de facto, informal actor authorized/responsible to acquire land for the city’s greenspace program. However, federal, state, and local Extension law forbid (do not authorize or require) the Office to acquire land for community greenspace. | -2 | 2 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Protect | Partnership’s informal agreement places JCCE Office in a position to protect greenspace for community use. However, federal, state, and local extension laws do not authorize (or require) the Office to engage in greenspace protection. LMG also undermines greenspace protection by granting short-term (temporary) lease agreements and failing to commit to permanent greenspace. | -2 | -1 | -2 | 0 | ||||
Insurance (Property) | Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office de facto provider of insurance for the city’s sponsored greenspaces. Formal lease agreements (on some of the properties) formally require property insurance. However, federal, state, and local laws governing Extension do not authorize the Office to provide insurance for community greenspace as primary provider. | -2 | 1 | 1 | 1 | ||||
Fiscal: External |
Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office informally responsible to manage the city’s greenspace program (including land acquisition) in a fiscally efficient way. However, federal, state, and local Extension laws do not authorize (or require) the Office to receive external funds for community greenspace acquisition. Landowners informally allow the Office to use the land free of cost. | -2 | 0 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Fiscal: Self-Sufficiency |
JCCE Office was not formally authorized to use Extension taxes to fund land acquisition. But by virtue of its status as an Extension Office, JCCE Office informally receives land donations for temporary use. | -2 | 0 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Pollution Remediation | JCCE Office’s de facto, informal role as land manager for the city’s sponsored greenspaces creates an informal responsibility to address soil pollution. Federal, state, and local law authorize (and require) JCCE Office to offer soil-testing services for agriculture. However, the Office is not formally authorized (or required), specifically as primary community greenspace owner/manager. | 0 | 0 | 0 | 2 | ||||
Table 5
Table 5. Jefferson County Cooperative Extension (JCCE) Office’s operational (production) capacities: land management. Note: AUTH - authority; F - formal; IF - informal; LMG - Louisville metro government; RESP - responsibility; UK - University of Kentucky. Five-point scale: -2 (definitely lacks) to 2 (definitely possesses).
Principle (capacity) | Description | AUTH | RESP | ||||||
F | IF | F | IF | ||||||
Coordinate | Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office de facto, informal coordinator for the program’s greenspace management (informal responsibility). However, Federal, state, and local Extension laws do not authorize (or require) the Office to play this role. Additionally, LMG and UK exclude JCCE Office from critical coordination activities. | -2 | 0 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Manage | Partnership’s informal agreement informally authorizes and requires JCCE Office to ensure that each sponsored greenspace is properly managed. Lease agreements (some properties) formally require management. However, federal, state, and local Extension laws do not authorize/require the Office to manage community greenspace. | -2 | 2 | 0 | 2 | ||||
Transfer Rights Responsibility | Partnership’s informal agreement authorizes/requires the Office to transfer rights and responsibility of greenspace management to communities. However, federal, state, and local extension laws (and the MOA) do not officially authorize or require the transfer. | -2 | 1 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Insurance (Liability) | Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office de facto provider of personal injury insurance on sponsored sites. Formal lease agreements (some properties) require liability insurance. However, federal, state, and local Extension laws do not authorize the Office to provide liability insurance for this purpose. | -2 | 1 | 1 | 1 | ||||
Regulate |
Partnership’s informal agreement makes JCCE Office informally responsible to regulate the garden users (e.g., monitoring, rule enforcement). Formal lease agreements (some properties) require the Office to regulate onsite activity. However, federal, state, and local Extension laws do not authorize/require this role for greenspace management. LMG, UK, and UK’s Extension Director override the Office’s regulatory actions. | -2 | 0 | 0 | 2 | ||||
Fiscal: External | MOA provides $350,000 annually; $50,000 was informally allocated for greenspace, but this is insufficient. Federal, state, and local Extension laws authorize (and require) funding be used for general operations, not community greenspace. | -2 | 0 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Fiscal: Self-Sufficiency | JCCE Office lacks authority to collect/use Extension taxes but is informally authorized to collect approximately $10,000 in garden user fees (which is insufficient). | -2 | 0 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Provide Services | Federal, state, and local Extension laws (and the MOA) authorize/require JCCE Office to provide general research, education, outreach services. Partnership’s informal agreement authorizes and requires these services for its greenspace program. | 2 | 2 | 2 | 2 | ||||
Provide Water | JCCE Office’s role as de facto, informal manager of the city’s sponsored greenspaces requires it to provide water access. However, federal, state, and local laws (including the MOA) do not authorize or require the Office to provide greenspace water. | -2 | 2 | -2 | 2 | ||||
Table 6
Table 6. Jefferson County Cooperative Extension (JCCE) Office’s capacity for organizational self-governance. Note: AUTH - authority; DM - decision making; LMG - Louisville metro government; RESP - Responsibility; RM - rule making; UK - University of Kentucky; UK Extension - UK’s Cooperative Extension Service. Five-point scale: -2 (definitely lacks) to 2 (definitely possesses).
Principle (capacity) | Description | AUTH | RESP |
Constitutive | JCCE Office is not authorized to establish the organization’s core structures (e.g., roles, committees), mission, rules, or decisions; constitutive authority is instead hierarchically bestowed to UK, UK Extension, the District Board, and LMG (i.e., Mayor). JCCE Office is required (via codified responsibilities/constraints) to defer constitutive power to these supervisory agents. | -2 | 2 |
Constitutional DM | JCCE Office is not authorized to make fundamental decisions for its own governance. Constitutional DM is bestowed to UK, UK Extension, District Board, LMG. JCCE Office is required (via codified responsibilities) to defer Constitutional DM authority to higher agents. | -2 | 2 |
Constitutional RM | Similar restrictions (see Constitutional DM) apply to JCCE Office’s Constitutional RM authority and responsibility. | -2 | 2 |
Administrative DM | JCCE Office (Director and staff) is authorized (and required) to make routine decisions and best practices for basic operations in regular implementation of core functions, as long as these actions align with existing Constitutive and Constitutional constraints. | 2 | 2 |
Administrative RM | JCCE Office’s Director is authorized to make and implement rules and procedures for the routine operation of the Office and its programs. However, these rules or procedures are subject to approval by UK’s Director of Extension and may be overridden; the Office is required to comply with such oversight. | 0 | 2 |
Regulation | JCCE Office’s Director is authorized to regulate its staff members in routine operations, including to resolve conflicts. However, UK’s Director of Extension must approve non-routine regulatory actives and intervenes to regulate the Director and/or Staff. The Office Director and staff are required to comply with this oversight. | 0 | 2 |
Fiscal Viability: External | JCCE Office is authorized to receive $350,000 annually from LMG for general operations, and additional salary, training, and equipment from UK and UK Extension (these are formalized as fiscal obligations). | 2 | 2 |
Fiscal Viability: Internal | Extension districts are authorized to collect taxes to fund their operations; however, JCCE District was denied this authorization, and commensurately assigned a formal taxation ban (i.e., responsibility to not tax). | -2 | 2 |
Table 7
Table 7. Partnership’s capacities for multi-actor cooperation. Note: AUTH - authority; Evaluation - scores; NS - NeighborSpace; RESP - Responsibility. Five-point scale ranging from -2 (definitely lacks) to 2 (definitely possesses), with “0” (not mentioned/mixed) mid-point.
Principle (capacity) | Description | AUTH | RESP | De facto |
Communication | Federal, state, and local Extension laws authorize Extension Offices to communicate with diverse stakeholders. However, the laws do not provide authorization or responsibility specifically for community greenspace governance or management (see also, official MOA). In practice, the partners rarely communicate. Communication is typically unilateral. Interviews revealed major misconceptions about the program among the partners, stemming from poor communication. | 0 | 0 | -2 |
Shared DM | Federal, state, and local Extension laws authorize and require Extension Services to confer with key stakeholders when making programmatic decisions. However decision making within Extension is designed to be hierarchical. The informal greenspace partnership has no formal, authorized or required decision-making body to share decision authority or responsibility. In practice, JCCE Office is excluded or marginalized in critical decisions. The partners rarely, if ever, hold collaborative decision events to govern the partnership or the greenspace program. | 0 | 0 | -2 |
Enforcement | The partnership has no official, legally binding contract. However some greenspaces have a formal lease agreement. Therefore, direct enforcement is weak, or mixed. In practice, the stakeholders rely on indirect methods (e.g., financial threats, neighborhood complaints, landscape ordinance code enforcement). These methods have weak or mixed regulatory force. | 0 | 0 | 0 |
Sociopolitical Boundaries | Extension laws (see also, official MOA) do not explicitly pertain to community greenspace. Most roles and responsibilities of the greenspace program and partnership are informal and unclear. | -2 | -2 | -1 |
Ecological Boundaries | Each greenspace’s location is officially documented. Extension laws authorize and require JCCE Office to deliver ecological education (e.g., urban agriculture). In practice, each greenspace’s location is well known and marked (e.g., fences, signs). Basic environmental characteristics are also well known. | 2 | 2 | 2 |
Equity | Federal, state, and local Extension laws (see also, official MOA) do not authorize or require equitable costs (financial, labor) or benefits in decision making, governance, or greenspace management. In practice, JCCE Office is excluded from critical decisions and underfunded, but carries most of the burden to manage the greenspaces and greenspace program. The program failed to improve equitable greenspace access (relatively few residents benefit). | -2 | -2 | -2 |
Accountability: Upward, Downward, Horizontal | Formal communication, decision making, and enforcement (see prior entries) convey mixed authorization and responsibility for accountability. LMG, UK, UK’s Extension Director are authorized/required to hold JCCE Office accountable (upward), but not specifically for community greenspace. The Office lacks formal mechanisms to hold these higher agents accountable (downward) and limited formal capacity to hold greenspace users accountable (upward). Community members lack robust formal mechanisms to hold higher agents (including JCCE Office) accountable, except via indirect methods (e.g., complaints to local councilpersons). Due to informality and deficient communication/decision making, the partners lack robust formal methods to hold each other accountable (horizontal). In practice, any stakeholder’s ability to hold another accountable is weak or mixed, depending on the targeted action, actor(s), and situation. | 0 | 0 | 0 |