The following is the established format for referencing this article:
Wagner, J., J. K. L. Koehler, and R. A. Hope. 2025. Managing contractual uncertainty for drinking water services in rural Mali. Ecology and Society 30(1):28.ABSTRACT
Contracts allocate rights, obligations, and risks between various parties to achieve specific results. In response to slow progress to deliver safe drinking water to rural populations, governments across Africa are increasingly introducing contracts with professional service providers. Contracts for drinking water service provision are designed to align operational outcomes with financial objectives. Yet, professional drinking water service providers generally miss revenue goals despite meeting their contractually agreed service delivery obligations. This mismatch between contractual expectations and outcomes in implementation speaks to wider issues of contract incompleteness. Contract theory indicates that renegotiation is a critical mechanism to adapt an incomplete contract design to uncertainties in operational and financial performance materializing during contract implementation. In this article we examine how contract incompleteness affects the sustainability of professional rural water service delivery and explore how and to what extent an incomplete contract might be addressed. Applying contract theory to a professional service delivery model operating in rural Mali, the empirical analysis uses qualitative methods to provide new insights on the process and consequences of contract renegotiation. Results of our case study show that contract renegotiation is conditional on the original parties’ agreement to adapt the contract and also requires the involvement of external actors and capital to address the shortcomings of an incomplete contract design. In the Mali case, we find that the contract is incomplete because of the inability to enforce local water demand, hindering progress to revenue targets aligned with commercial finance. This condition is likely to hold in most rural contexts requiring contracting models for rural water services to combine public and philanthropic funding and private finance to deliver on desired outcomes.
INTRODUCTION
Contracts are part of everyday life. They govern interactions in a wide array of sectors and structure related activities, including employment, bank services, utilities (e.g., energy, water, or sanitation), insurance, or mobile phones. In its most basic form, a contract is an arrangement between two or more parties that allocates rights and obligations that can be legally enforced. Such an arrangement involves the exchange of goods or services, or a promise to exchange those at a future date and defines expected outcomes. Finally, a contract provides a process for resolution of contract infringements and termination (Hart and Moore 1988, North 1990).
We explore the extent to which contracts may provide a mechanism to support safe drinking water services in rural Africa where formal contracts are not usually applied. Rural water services are commonly delivered through informal community-based management. Despite significant investments in community approaches, progress has been largely unsatisfactory in maintaining rural water infrastructure (RWSN 2010, Foster 2013, van den Broek and Brown 2015, Whaley et al. 2019), leaving approximately 25%–30% of waterpoints in rural Africa non-functional (Foster et al. 2020).
In response to this limited performance, professional service providers are increasingly being mandated across rural Africa to ensure the operational sustainability of water supplies (McNicholl et al. 2021, Nilsson et al. 2021, WHO et al. 2022). This institutional shift toward more formal service delivery is organized through contracts that are designed to align operational outcomes with financial objectives (Hope and Rouse 2013, Hope et al. 2020). Contracts between professional service providers and governments may offer a suitable means to attract investment and capacity to accelerate progress toward the Sustainable Development Goal for Water, SDG 6.
Criteria pertaining to the drinking water service ladder (UNICEF and WHO 2023) can provide guidance on specific service outcomes that a rural water contract may define. Once contractually agreed, outcomes, such as water quantity, quality, or service reliability can be tracked over time to assess compliance, inform enforcement, and increase efficiency. In exchange, it is expected that a contract clarifies the service provider’s revenue base, mainly by granting the right to collect tariffs from users (Gia and Fugelsnes 2010, Kleemeier and Narkevic 2010, Kleemeier and Lockwood 2012, McNicholl et al. 2019). This is in line with a policy principle, widely established across sub-Saharan Africa, stipulating that operation and maintenance costs of drinking water services are to be covered through tariffs paid by users (Foster 2016, Hope et al. 2019).
Although these policy objectives inform contract design for sustainable rural water services, in practice, contracts fall short of achieving anticipated results. Evidence indicates that professional service providers generally deliver on their obligation to provide drinking water services in accordance with contracted performance indicators. Yet, these service providers only rarely generate sufficient revenue via user payments to cover operating costs (McNicholl et al. 2020, 2021, Foster et al. 2022, Smith et al. 2023). In other words, while operational results are achieved, revenue goals are missed, despite contracts that are meant to promote financial sustainability are in place.
This mismatch between contractual expectations and outcomes in implementation speaks to wider issues of contractual incompleteness, a phenomenon well-studied by contract theory (Hart and Moore 1988, 2008, Hart 2003, 2017). Hart and Moore (1988) demonstrate that contracts are necessarily incomplete, yet adaptable throughout implementation. An important mechanism for adaptation consists in renegotiation allowing parties to adapt an incomplete contract design to uncertainties regarding anticipated performance. Even though contract theory appears as a salient conceptual tool, it has not yet been applied to rural water services. Therefore, in this article we draw on contract theory to provide a comprehensive understanding of the prospects and limitations of formal contracts with professional providers for delivering sustainable rural water services. What can contract parties do when contractually defined outcomes are not achieved? What are the implications for performance when changes to a contract are made? We explore these and related questions to generate new evidence on how to effectively sustain rural drinking water services.
CONCEPTUAL FOUNDATIONS
Incomplete contract design and renegotiation
Formal contracts form part of the human-made strategies for organizing and sustaining societal relations and economic performance and are established to reduce “uncertainties involved in human interaction” (North 1990:25). Any contract design may vary regarding the number of parties involved, the duration of the contract, or still the specific characteristics of the contracted outcomes. Yet, their common feature is that they provide the structure necessary to exchange goods and services over time. Here, Hart and Moore (2008) demonstrate that contracts act as reference points, shaping future performance by anchoring initial expectations of the contracting parties. When signing a contract, parties know how future payoffs will be distributed amongst them, how resources flow, or how risks are allocated.
This reduction of uncertainty is particularly relevant for more complex exchanges of services or goods that involve asset-specific investments (Goldberg and Erickson 1987, Hart and Moore 1988, Williamson 1995, 2002, Hart 2003). Long-term contracts may mitigate risks associated with the lock-in effect of asset-specificity where “buyers cannot easily turn to alternative sources of supply, while suppliers can redeploy the specialized assets to their next best use or user only at a loss of productive value” (Williamson 2002:176). Hence, when specific investments, such as infrastructure, are required for an exchange, parties may write a long-term contract, providing the necessary foundation for relevant investments.
Regarding the outcomes permitted by a contract, parties must navigate trade-offs between flexibility and rigidity (Hart and Moore 2008, Fehr et al. 2011). A rigid contract anchors parties’ expectations through a fixed price and clearly defines the specific characteristics of the relevant good or service. A flexible contract, on the other hand, seeks to set a price range for a good or service whose specific characteristics will be defined during contract implementation. This allows parties to adjust the outcomes permitted by the contract to the contingent states of the world but may lead to friction and inefficiencies as the buyer and seller may have different preferences regarding which outcome to choose: “when the contract permits more than one outcome, each party may feel entitled to a different outcome” (Hart and Moore 2008:3). Besides, costs associated with writing and implementing a flexible contract are generally high (Hart and Moore 2008, Gottardi et al. 2017, Hart 2017), and the relative simplicity of a rigid contract seems to be appealing to contracting parties (Fehr et al. 2011, Gottardi et al. 2017). Therefore, in practice, parties tend to write more rigid contracts, particularly when asset-specific investments are involved (Hart and Moore 2008, Hart 2017).
Regardless of its rigidity or flexibility, contract theory suggests that any contract is necessarily incomplete (Hart and Moore 1988, 2008, Hart 2003, 2017). This inherent incompleteness is likely to become apparent during contract implementation when parties realize that specific issues have been overlooked in the initial contract design and expected outcomes will not be achieved (Hart and Moore 1988, Sansom et al. 2003, OECD 2011, Awortwi 2012). As gaps between contractually agreed and actual performance outcomes arise, specific mechanisms internal to the arrangement may be mobilized to address such shortcomings (Ménard 2004).
One such mechanism to address the inherent flaws of an incomplete contract, as demonstrated by Hart and Moore (1988), is renegotiation. Through renegotiation, contracting parties can adjust contractual terms to the uncertainties and contingent circumstances unfolding during contract execution, thereby adapting an initial contract design to observed performance. For instance, renegotiation can improve the efficiency of a contract as it enables the parties to readjust the expected outcomes to information from implementation (Hart and Moore 2008, Fehr et al. 2011). Besides, adapting contractual arrangements through experimentation (Huitema et al. 2009) may provide opportunities for wider learning to inform contract design and service delivery practice.
In addition to challenges related to incompleteness, for a contract to perform, the wider institutional environment matters, that is, the capacity of the contract parties or external actors to enforce contractual terms (North 1990, Messick 2005). The legal enforceability and regulation of contracts varies in a spectrum from conditions of mature contract markets to more informal social contexts. As such, it may be challenging to introduce formal contracting approaches to rural areas of developing countries where the reach of enforcement capabilities of state authorities is limited (North 1990, Messick 2005, Herbst 2015).
Finally, the scope of renegotiation is dependent on the willingness of the parties to renegotiate (Frydlinger and Hart 2024). Reputation and loyalty between the contracting parties can enable renegotiation to address incomplete contracts (Athias and Saussier 2018, Beuve and Saussier 2021), particularly when formal enforcement mechanisms are missing (North 1990, Messick 2005). Frydlinger and Hart (2024) demonstrate that frequent and transparent communication between the parties during contract implementation can help when changes to a contract are needed.
Rural water service delivery in Africa
The delegation of service delivery functions through contracts is widely established as a policy principle in rural water supply (Gia and Fugelsnes 2010, Kleemeier and Narkevic 2010, Kleemeier and Lockwood 2012, Simone et al. 2016). In various countries across sub-Saharan Africa, service authorities holding the infrastructure assets must delegate service delivery to a service provider, which can either be a public entity, private enterprise, or a legally recognized water user association. In several other countries, the involvement of the private sector in rural water service delivery is encouraged but the modalities of this participation are not further specified (Fig. 1).
The increasing interest in contractual approaches to service delegation is part of a wider institutional shift in rural water (Nilsson et al. 2021). In comparison to traditional community-based management, professional service providers deploy formal contracts tailored toward long-term service delivery, including repairs and wider support services for rural drinking water infrastructure (Lockwood et al. 2021). By defining expected service outcomes through contractual frameworks, results can be tracked by key performance metrics such as volume of water, local revenue, water quality, or repair time (McNicholl et al. 2019, Charles et al. 2023). This provides a basis for accountability, oversight, and user protection (Gerlach 2019, Lockwood 2021). In exchange, the contract defines a tariff that users are expected to pay for the service received (Gia and Fugelsnes 2010, Kleemeier and Narkevic 2010, Janssens 2011, Koehler et al. 2018, McNicholl et al. 2019).
In addition to the specific service outcomes that a contract may define, the particular type of contract in place has implications on how risks are distributed amongst contracting authority and service provider. In the literature three main contract types have been identified for rural water services, ranging from management, over lease, or affermage, to concession contracts (Table 1).
Generally, delegation involves a transfer of financial risk from the asset holder to the operator. Depending on the scope of delegated service functions and associated risks, the duration of the contract will vary (Sansom et al. 2003, Gia and Fugelsnes 2010, Janssens 2011, OECD 2011, Hydrophil 2013, WSP 2014). For instance, if a contract requires the service provider to make infrastructure investments, creating major financial risks, the time frame for the contract will typically be of at least 15 years to allow for a sufficient pay-back horizon.
Yet, regardless of the particular contract type in place, revenue goals of contracted rural drinking water service delivery models are not achieved in many cases (Katuva et al. 2016, McNicholl et al. 2020, 2021, Koehler et al. 2021, Foster et al. 2022, Smith et al. 2023), pointing to wider issues of contractual incompleteness. Because “contracts are often drawn up using incorrect assumptions” (Gia and Fugelsnes 2010:16), it is only during contract implementation that mismatches between expected and actual outcomes materialize, suggesting that the initial contract design did not adequately consider the specific economics of rural water and associated uncertainties.
Uncertainties related to rural water user behavior
Rural water is characterized by particular geographical, spatial, socio-political, and economic factors shaping its specific economics and uncertainties. Importantly, the prevalence of alternative or seasonal water sources on which rural users potentially rely leads to uncertain demand because rural households can choose between various water sources for different uses (White et al. 1972, Briscoe et al. 1981, Thompson et al. 2001, Martínez-Santos 2017, Hoque and Hope 2018, Gross and Elshiewy 2019).
This specificity may not always be considered in policy and practice, leading to flawed assumptions about the role and obligations of water users. It is assumed that users will use and pay for the service as planned. However, rural water is characterized by a high degree of autonomy of users, leading to relative demand uncertainty. The non-exclusive nature of rural water constitutes a fundamental challenge when a contract links revenue to water production and sales, thereby effectively allocating the commercial risk to the service provider (Janssens 2011). Also, the limited ability of rural users to pay may further constrain demand for professional rural water services (Hoque 2023).
In addition, evidence indicates that user demand and payments are contingent on the quality of services provided (Nauges and Whittington 2010, Foster and Hope 2017, Van Houtven et al. 2017, Shongwe and Dlamini 2021). Hence, a service provider has an incentive to influence user demand to generate sufficient revenues. Engaging in value creation by delivering high-quality services that people want and value (Garrick et al. 2017, 2020, Hope et al. 2020) appears as an adequate strategy for service providers to increase their revenue (Carter et al. 2010). Here, contractually agreed service attributes pertaining to water quantity, quality, affordability, proximity, and reliability may provide guidance on key priorities of rural water users (Hope et al. 2020).
Following the rationale that contracts can be renegotiated during contract implementation (Hart and Moore 1988), contractually agreed outcomes and conditions may be revisited to promote more sustainable services. In the case of rural water services, such contractually agreed outcomes may reflect service attributes pertaining to water quantity, quality, affordability, proximity, and reliability (UNGA 2015).
To examine the role of formal contracts and the implications of renegotiation and service adaptations for sustainable rural water services, we investigate how contract incompleteness affects the sustainability of professional service delivery and explore how and to what extent an incomplete contract design might be addressed. Using the contractual model of a professional drinking water service provider in rural Mali as a case study, we analyze how different actors behave to overcome the limitations of an incomplete contract and assess how service adaptations allow to address these shortcomings. Drawing on contracting documents, interviews, and field reports, we illustrate how renegotiation and changes in service attributes influence contractual outcomes.
Similar to Frydlinger and Hart (2024), we use contract theory to qualitatively illustrate the prospects and limitations of implementing formal contracts in a specific context. Following a pragmatic research philosophy (Feilzer 2010, Kaushik and Walsh 2019), the paper integrates contract theory, grounded in a positivist epistemology, with a constructivist methodological design. This approach constitutes the originality of our paper, providing new conceptual and empirical insights into the extent to which contracts with professional service providers can serve as an effective mechanism to enhance the operational and financial sustainability of drinking water services in rural Africa.
CASE PRESENTATION
Context
Mali’s water sector is based on the Water Act (Republique du Mali 2002), which defines the general institutional framework, stipulating local governments as service authorities for rural water supply (Article 49). Municipalities, Mali’s lowest government level, bear the ultimate responsibility for drinking water services on their territory (Article 50) but must delegate service provision to a provider, which can either be a private or public entity, or a legally recognized water user association (Article 45). The delegation must be organized via a formal contract (Article 51) including a service level agreement that clarifies terms and conditions of the service (DNH 2007). In our case, 30 local governments in the Region of Sikasso, located in the south of Mali, decided to contract UDUMA, a professional service delivery company with a business model based on full cost recovery through user payments (van der Wilk 2019).
UDUMA’s service delivery model
Through the initial contracts signed in November 2018 (UDUMA 2018, unpublished report), these municipalities grant UDUMA for a duration of 15 years (§ 5) the exclusive right (§ 6) to set up its service model in their respective territories, covering all existing hand pumps for community drinking water supply, and to collect tariffs from users (§ 1). In exchange, the provider invests in the rehabilitation of the water supply infrastructure, which will be handed over to the service authorities after the end of the contract (§ 7), and commits to their subsequent operation and maintenance. This contractual relationship, where an operator invests in existing infrastructure and is responsible for its operations and maintenance and bill collection from customers, is a particular type of a lease contract, called affermage (see Table 1). As part of the contract, UDUMA must ensure a bi-annual financial and technical reporting to the service authorities for accountability purposes (§ 12) and pay a fee of 3% on its annual billed and paid turnover (§ 20). Local governments have hence a financial incentive to adhere to the contractual agreement (UDUMA 2017, unpublished report).
Regarding the user-provider relationship, UDUMA commits to providing a reliable service, guaranteeing a maximum downtime of 72 hours per waterpoint, and must conduct regular water quality monitoring and relevant interventions in case bacterial contamination is detected (Annex 2 of the contract). In exchange, water users must pay a volumetric, pay-as-you fetch tariff of 500 FCFA ($0.80) per m³ (§ 21 and Annex 2), in accordance with Mali’s tariff policy for rural water supply (DNH 2007). Under a pay-as-you-fetch (PAYF) approach, users must directly pay the caretaker for the amount of water they collect from the hand pump.
Through the guaranteed service, users are insured against operational risks of hand pump failure and can mitigate financial risks of high repair costs, which constitute a major factor for sustained downtime (Jones 2013, Foster 2013, Foster and Hope 2016). Environmental risks related to groundwater pollution are addressed to some extent through regular water quality testing and water safety plans implemented at the village level (§ 14 and Annex 2). UDUMA’s contract may be considered rigid as it defines expected outcomes clearly and “take[s] price off the table” (Hart and Moore 2008:25).
UDUMA’s initial business model assumes a daily water usage of at least 2 m³ per hand pump and projects no default in volumetric payments (100% payment collection), effectively tying revenue to water demand, billing, and bill collection. Because its financial model is based on cost recovery through user payments, UDUMA has clear expectations about the outcomes of its exclusive contracts. Once contracts are in place, officializing a shared understanding of the terms of the agreement, financial sustainability will be achieved because people will use and pay for the service provided (UDUMA 2017, 2018, unpublished reports).
The formal contracts are complemented by informal community agreements (§ 15 and Annex 4), linking UDUMA with local governments and user communities (Fig. 2). These arrangements at the local level are signed by representatives of the three parties and are meant to ensure social acceptance of the service delivery approach, contributing to “institutional sustainability” (UDUMA 2017:12, unpublished report).
To cover a share of the initial capital costs required for rehabilitating hand pumps at scale, UDUMA received funding from the Netherlands Enterprise Agency (RVO), providing a grant of €3 million through its Sustainable Water Fund (RVO 2017). In addition, the long-term contracts signed with the municipalities enabled UDUMA to secure private loans at market rates of a total amount of €2 million, thereby creating liabilities. Because the French commercial banks required guarantees (van der Wilk 2019), the affermage contracts turned into an “essential asset” (personal communication with UDUMA team, 19 July 2021). They mattered to build confidence in the long-term nature of the investment case, especially because the “political risk associated with investing in developing countries ... caused hesitation” (van der Wilk 2019:7). The business model at scale was meant to allow “for reimbursing the initial 40% private capital investment” while generating an adequate return on investment (van der Wilk 2019:5).
Evolution of the contractual model
Yet, the contracts encountered implementation issues on the operational level, leading to unexpected revenue shortfalls. As outlined above, UDUMA’s initial business model assumed an average daily water usage of 2 m³ per hand pump and projected no default in volumetric payments, effectively tying revenue to water demand and payment collection. Operational and financial data from the first two years of operations, however, revealed that these assumptions were flawed. Only a quarter of the anticipated daily water volume was actually used, and users paid only 40% of water collected, emphasizing that its contracts were incomplete because of the inability to guarantee water demand and enforce volumetric payments. The payment enforcement challenge encountered at hand pumps under the volumetric payment modality is related to the fact that waterpoint caretakers in charge of payment collection did “not have the capacity to impose themselves when needed” (UDUMA 2021:28, unpublished report). This illustrates wider issues of enforcing formal contracts in settings where more informal social practices and specific community dynamics may be at play.
In response to the observed performance, UDUMA used Article 33 of its contract to renegotiate contractual conditions with local governments prompting two service adaptations related to water quantity and tariff design (UDUMA 2021, unpublished report). Figure 3 provides an overview of the evolution of and relevant changes to UDUMA’s contractual model.
UDUMA proposed to local governments to initially trial solar-powered water kiosks in 10 villages, reflecting the diverse geographical, socioeconomic, and environmental conditions of its service area. The infrastructure upgrade increased the production capacity of the existing waterpoint initially equipped with a manual pump supplying one spout to a solar kiosk supplying three on-demand taps. As part of the contractual revisions, UDUMA changed payment modalities at hand pumps by replacing direct volumetric payments through a monthly flat fee of 15,000 FCFA ($24) per waterpoint, with no limit on water use (UDUMA 2021, unpublished report).
METHODOLOGY
UDUMA’s contractual model emerges from dialogue involving multiple stakeholders. Because “important aspects of institutions and institutional change appear in the form of qualitative evidence” (Skarbek 2020:409), conducting a qualitative case study seems appropriate as it presents an opportunity for in-depth learning and exploratory investigation (Gerring 2004, Flyvbjerg 2006, 2011, Yin 2009).
We justify the case selection with the “revelatory” and “longitudinal” nature of the UDUMA case (Yin 2009). First, investigating UDUMA’s model may be revelatory for other contexts. The role of commercial, long-term contracts in the delivery of rural water services remains empirically underexplored. This gap is mainly due to the limited availability of cases in Africa, where “most countries have not demanded significant investments in infrastructure from their private partners” (Kleemeier and Lockwood 2012:1). That a private enterprise commits to carrying sizable commercial risks is rare for the provision of rural water services and may thus be revelatory for other contexts. Because professional service delivery is a wider trend in rural water across sub-Saharan Africa, empirical insights from this case study may be of relevance for other service delivery models and contexts. Second, “studying the same single case at two or more different points in time” (Yin 2009:49) allows to analyze how a contract-based service delivery model evolves over time. This can provide insights on the underlying processes and consequences of contractual changes in service delivery.
To unpack the process and outcomes of contract renegotiation, the empirical research applies qualitative approaches to data collection and analysis that will be presented in detail in the following sections. Prior to any data collection and analysis, ethical approval was obtained from the Research Ethics Committee at the corresponding author’s university (SOGE 1A2020-195 and SOGE 1A2020-210).
Data sources and collection
The study draws on various sources of primary and secondary evidence. For the collection of the empirical material, specific sampling strategies were developed, guiding the data collection process. To contextualize the study case in Mali’s national water policy context, semi-structured expert interviews with representatives (n = 14) from organizations intervening in the water sector in Mali were conducted online throughout the year 2021. To ground the implementation of UDUMA’s contractual model and understand the implications of the service adaptations, in-person fieldwork was conducted in May 2022 in 9 villages of UDUMA’s service area to interview a total of 36 water users, 8 representatives of local governments, 9 representatives of village committees, and 3 UDUMA field staff. In addition, the lead author conducted 6 in-person workshops and 13 online meetings with staff from UDUMA France between 2020 and 2023 to understand the service model and trace its evolution. Finally, interviews with representatives of relevant funding agencies were conducted to clarify their role in UDUMA’s model.
Fieldwork in Mali: interviews with local stakeholders
In recognition of UDUMA’s institutional model (Fig. 2), the corresponding author conducted in-person fieldwork in May 2022 in 9 villages that are part of UDUMA’s service area to interview representatives from municipalities as contracting authorities, drinking water users using and paying for UDUMA’s service, and community representatives. During interviews with the respective stakeholders, notes using pen and paper were taken to limit any perceived power imbalances between participants and researcher (Fetterman 2010, Mannay and Morgan 2015). Subsequently, these notes were transcribed for further analysis.
The field sites (see Appendix 1, Table S1 and Fig. S1) were purposely chosen. As presented above, UDUMA selected 10 sites across 9 municipalities to trial solar kiosks. The selected waterpoints were upgraded between March and May 2021. Payment modalities at the remaining hand pumps were shifted from volumetric payments to monthly flat fees. One year after these changes, allowing relevant stakeholders to gain experience with the new infrastructure and payment modality, fieldwork was conducted to understand their perceptions of the service changes prompted by the contract revisions.
UDUMA facilitated the fieldwork by providing support in terms of logistics (dispatching a car and driver). In addition, UDUMA’s field officer in charge of community engagement acted as a door-opener to the various stakeholders and ensured translation between French and Bambara. Although the UDUMA employee’s intimate understanding of the fieldwork setting was crucial for enabling the data collection, this set-up may have created an interviewer bias because the interviewees’ opinions may have interfered with the relationship existing between them and UDUMA as the target organization.
A total of 36 semi-structured interviews with water users asking open-ended questions (Tong et al. 2007, Narayanasamy 2009) were conducted to understand their subjective perceptions, opinions, and experiences of the services delivered by UDUMA. Three to five users were interviewed at each site. The interviews (see questionnaire in Appendix 2) covered key themes such as the degree of user satisfaction, practices, motivations, and interpretations regarding UDUMA’s service and related service adaptations. The sample strategy for the user interviews was informed by purposive sampling to recruit participants who have the potential to provide rich and diverse data pertinent to the research question (Tong et al. 2007).
In addition, contextual data through waterpoint mappings were collected. The main alternative water sources in each village (e.g., community wells, hand pumps, small piped systems, surface water sources) were identified and source characteristics, such as functionality, perceived water quality, and management arrangements (e.g., ownership and water price), were recorded using a mobile data collection tool (https://odk.ona.io/). In case people were fetching water at alternative sources, short questions were asked to understand their motivations and perceptions of UDUMA’s service.
Semi-structured interviews with eight representatives from local governments were conducted to gather insights on the perspective of the service authorities as formal party to the bilateral contract. The interview respondents were either the municipality’s mayor, Secretary General, or the officer in charge of Water, Sanitation, and Hygiene (WASH). The interviews focused on understanding the municipality’s rationale for initially joining the arrangement and its perception of the relationship with UDUMA.
Informal discussions with village and community representatives were designed to unpack collective perceptions of UDUMA’s service. Because the community agreements were meant to ensure community buy-in, the conversations were tailored to understand the communities’ perceptions and motivations shaping the outcomes of the contract arrangements.
Data on the provider’s perspective: interviews and project documents
Three interviews with local UDUMA staff in Mali were conducted to collect information on the provider’s perspective regarding the implementation of the contract. Particularly, insights on the application of specific contractual clauses, such as payment enforcement, as well as the wider processes of renegotiation were gathered.
In addition to the in-person interviews with staff from UDUMA Mali, the lead author conducted a total of 19 in-person and online meetings with staff from UDUMA France throughout the research process spanning 2020 to 2023 (see anonymized list of meetings in Appendix 3). These exchanges allowed to build a detailed understanding of UDUMA’s service model and its evolution.
Lastly, the formal service delegation contracts (initial version from 2018 and revised in 2021) and related appendices were retrieved from UDUMA (UDUMA 2018, 2021, 2021, unpublished reports). In addition, relevant project documents were compiled, consisting of UDUMA’s initial project proposal to RVO (UDUMA 2017, unpublished report), various annual progress reports (UDUMA 2018, 2019, 2020, 2021, 2022, unpublished reports), a report from the Regional Water Directorate (DRH) from 2020 (DRH 2020), and UDUMA’s formal request to RVO for a strategy change of the initial project (UDUMA 2021, unpublished report).
Data collection at the national level: expert interviews
For the interviews at the national level, a combination of purposive (seeking representatives of government, donors, civil society, and NGOs) and snowball sampling was used to identify 14 key informants from relevant technical and political organizations intervening in the water sector in Mali (see anonymized list of interviews in Appendix 4). The semi-structured expert interviews were conducted based on problem-centered expert interview methods (Merton and Kendall 1946, Witzel 1985) that restrict the information that is expected from interviewees but still allow respondents to identify aspects that are not addressed in the interview guideline (see questionnaire in Appendix 5). The interviews lasted approximately one hour and were conducted online in French by the corresponding author throughout the year 2021. Notes were taken during the interviews and subsequently transcribed for further analysis.
Data on the perspective of donors: interviews and project reports
Interviews with representatives of RVO and a private foundation were conducted to understand their role in the initial arrangement and for the evolution of UDUMA’s model. The semi-structured expert interviews (see questionnaire in Appendix 6) were conducted online by the corresponding author. Notes were taken during the interviews, and subsequently transcribed for further analysis. In addition, documentation (RVO 2022) and project data (RVO 2017) were retrieved online.
Data analysis
A single case study design attempts to provide an intensive analysis, characterized by detail, richness, and completeness. The internal validity of a case study is likely to improve when it combines various data sources to generate complementary insights that substantiate an argument (Ragin 1992, Gerring 2004, Flyvbjerg 2006, 2011). Therefore, we make use of triangulation of multiple sources of empirical material (Johnson et al. 2007, Yin 2009) to develop a coherent understanding of UDUMA’s contractual model and its evolution over time.
First, UDUMA’s initial and revised contracts were systematically reviewed to identify changes in contractual provisions. Subsequently, interview notes and project reports were qualitatively analyzed to generate insights on the respective perceptions and experiences of the various stakeholders to unravel the process leading to the identified changes in UDUMA’s contracts. Coding was done following an inductive, data-driven approach building on the concrete empirical material, while being guided by the research questions. The open-coding approach allowed to extract relevant information pertaining to perceptions and underlying motivations of the respective actors (Ercan and Marsh 2016, Silverman 2017). The qualitative analysis focused on identifying key relationships and recurring motives to trace changes of the contractual model. Synthesis of findings across the interviews and documents allowed to provide an expanded understanding of UDUMA’s contract design and evolution. Finally, user interviews were analyzed regarding factors related to water quantity, quality, affordability, reliability, and proximity and their relative priority. Importantly, we use interview excerpts to illustrate whether and how user responses change in regard to the contractually agreed adaptations in service delivery. Through the corroboration of empirical insights, we seek to establish coherent evidence for our conclusions.
For the use of direct quotations from expert interviews, expressed approval from interviewees was received because attribution to individuals may be possible despite anonymization. To avoid misinterpretation and to build credibility for the research’s conclusions, informant feedback was sought by sharing the manuscript with key informants, thereby further strengthening the study’s internal validity (Onwuegbuzie and Leech 2007).
RESULTS
In exploring the implementation of formal contracts for drinking water service delivery in rural Mali, we found evidence that rigid conditions do not necessarily allocate risks effectively. A certain degree of flexibility in UDUMA’s financial arrangements was required for the service model to continue. The results emphasize the role outside actors to the formal contracts played in shaping the renegotiation process of UDUMA’s initial contracts. Finally, we illustrate how contractual incompleteness was partially addressed by adapting specific service attributes, so that services better aligned with the preferences of water users and increased the enforceability of the contract.
Does a more rigid contract effectively allocate risks and responsibilities?
Within the first months since UDUMA had started its service in Sikasso, evidence indicated that the initial contract was incomplete. Although the first year of operations was deemed too early to draw conclusions about the sustainability of the model (UDUMA 2020:25f, unpublished report), UDUMA stated in its third progress report to RVO: “The past year (April 2020 to March 2021) has been eventful for Uduma. ... We have been forced to rethink our model” (2021:2, unpublished report). With an “average daily water use of 544 liters per pump” instead of the anticipated daily volume of 2 m³ and users paying “only 40% of total water used” (UDUMA 2021:31, unpublished report), the provider missed its viability target by a margin. The commercial risk of linking revenue to water production and sales materialized, suggesting that the initial contract had overlooked relevant contingencies (Hart and Moore 1988).
Despite the revenue shortfalls, UDUMA remained responsible for guaranteeing a reliable service in line with the performance indicators of its service level agreement, thereby covering operational risks related to hand pump failure. Because of the recurring commercial losses, UDUMA was “determined to take the necessary actions to adapt the model” (2021:6, unpublished report). Yet, the company was dependent on the agreement of the municipalities as contract authorities to permit changes to its rigid contracts.
Here, the Regional Water Directorate (DRH) came into play. With its role steered toward supporting contract implementation, DRH staff conducted four field missions in Sikasso in April 2020 to exchange with water users, village leaders, municipalities, and UDUMA to understand the reasons for non-compliance with the contractual arrangements. DRH recommended that UDUMA should consider installing solar-powered water kiosks or water ATMs to respond to the user population’s increasing demand for higher service levels (DRH 2020). Other donors such as UNICEF and Helvetas already had started investing in small solar-powered drinking water systems in the region of Sikasso, providing a precedent for user communities and local governments (interviews with Donor-ML-1, Donor-ML-2, Donor-ML-3 in 2021, and with UDUMA-1 in 2022).
Because the initial contracts limited the infrastructure portfolio to hand pumps (UDUMA 2018, §1, unpublished report), an amendment of the contract with the local governments was necessary. All 30 municipalities expressed their agreement with the proposed change in strategy. Because upgrading all existing hand pumps to solar kiosks was not feasible due to economic, technical, or environmental constraints, UDUMA proposed to change modalities for collecting user payments at hand pumps as the volumetric payment approach was contested by the user population (DRH 2020; UDUMA 2021, unpublished report). The municipalities signed amendments to the formal contracts with UDUMA allowing the installation of solar kiosks and the introduction of monthly flat fees at hand pumps (UDUMA 2021, unpublished reports).
By doing so, the municipalities not only ensured a reliable service to their populations but as well received improved infrastructure without having to provide additional commitments as UDUMA continued to carry the commercial and operational risks. Yet, the municipalities’ agreement to revise the contracts may not only be related to strategic considerations. Through UDUMA’s bi-annual reporting, the municipalities were aware of the significant operational and commercial challenges. Annual in-person meetings between UDUMA and the local governments were held to discuss problems related to contract implementation and fostered a “climate of trust” between the contracting parties (UDUMA 2021:15, unpublished report). As findings from contract theory suggest, frequent and transparent communication can promote a constructive relationship where contracting parties are more likely to apply principles of fairness or loyalty when changes to a contract are needed (Frydlinger and Hart 2024). During interviews, representatives of local governments indicated an appreciation of UDUMA’s continued commitment, despite the difficulties related to contract execution.
Although the formal parties to the bilateral contracts agreed to revise some of the rigid clauses, upgrading infrastructure required additional financial resources. However, the provider’s capital was constrained, providing no room for further investments, and potential losses. Because the revenue generated in Mali was insufficient to fulfil the loan obligations, ODIAL SOLUTIONS, UDUMA’s holding company, ensured the repayment of the €2 million loan, taking on the financial risks associated with the private capital investment (interview, UDUMA-3, 4 October 2023).
In October 2020, UDUMA presented the conclusions of the DRH report and a financial analysis to RVO to demand a re-allocation of funds toward the installation of solar kiosks. According to UDUMA (interview, UDUMA-2, 19 May 2022), RVO requested a proof-of-concept regarding the financial and operational sustainability of solar kiosks. RVO had committed to funding a public-private partnership tailored to installing 1400 hand pumps and subsequently maintaining them throughout 15 years, expecting to reach about 500,000 beneficiaries at relatively low costs (RVO 2017; UDUMA 2017, unpublished report).
In December 2020, a foundation supporting UDUMA’s wider work, agreed to fund the installation of 10 solar kiosks as a pilot project in nine municipalities (UDUMA 2021, unpublished report). When asked for the reasons to support piloting solar kiosks in Mali, the foundation staff commented:
Regarding the transition to solar in Mali, we already had a grant in place with UDUMA. This grant covered a broad range of activities in Mali and Burkina. Both countries are priority countries for us [the foundation]. UDUMA said that they wanted to re-allocate the money to pilot solar pumps in Mali. I approved since our grants do provide that flexibility. UDUMA can reallocate the money, as long as they remain within the boundaries of the initial grant approval. We knew that there was the RVO funding as part of the UDUMA model. But it was UDUMA who knew how to use our funding to convince RVO to change the initial strategy and to integrate the solar pumps into the portfolio. In the end, UDUMA used our flexible money to make a point they needed to demonstrate. (interview, 28 November 2023)
This agreement illustrates the foundation’s flexible funding approach, which permits risk taking in comparison to more traditional bilateral donor funding:
As part of our funding approach, we try to be non-prescriptive and flexible. We want to align with the grantee’s priorities. We give them the freedom to do what they think is best for them and their beneficiaries or clients. We want to be complementary to other funders, so we fund things that others do not want to or cannot fund. And we aim to do things where perceived risks are high. Mali as a context is risky, fine. UDUMA is an established company, linked to Vergnet Hydro. That is not very risky. But UDUMA’s business model is. It is a market-based approach for rural drinking water services, this is something very unusual in the rural water sector. I don’t think that they managed to really prove their business model yet. (interview, foundation staff, 28 November 2023)
The solar pilot proved to be catalytic for adapting UDUMA’s model. As UDUMA pointed out: “We were able to show that something works in Mali. At least, the revenues improved with the solar kiosks. This was certainly one of the reasons why RVO agreed to re-allocate the funding” (interview, UDUMA-2, 28 November 2023). The results of the pilot allowed UDUMA to secure additional funding from new partners, such as foundations organized in the “WASH Funders Group,” and to scale up investments in solar kiosks providing a basis to support continued work (UDUMA 2021, 2022, unpublished report).
However, RVO “needed time to come to a decision” regarding the transition to solar as investing in more expensive infrastructure meant that “the number of beneficiaries decreased significantly. We needed assurance that the proposed model would be accepted by the population and be viable” (interview, RVO staff, 7 December 2023). According to UDUMA, as part of RVO’s formal change request process, the Dutch Embassy in Mali was invited to give their perspective on the proposed strategy. In addition, RVO required that the change of the project aligned with the policy priorities of the Government of Mali. Here, the DRH report from 2020 allowed UDUMA to demonstrate its alignment with Mali’s official position (interview, UDUMA-2, 28 November 2023).
At the end of 2021, RVO agreed to re-allocate the initial funds permitting investments in solar kiosks:
We looked at the changes of the solar pilot and reflected on the implications forward. Data and feedback from the field showed that the willingness to pay, the revenues, and cost-recovery improved. And we saw that other donors were convinced as well. So, we agreed to the change in strategy. I think that we have still been quite flexible in our approach, particularly in comparison to the initial project. (interview, RVO staff, 7 December 2023)
UDUMA staff indicated that besides the encouraging financial performance registered at solar kiosks, the involvement of other donors was a salient argument for RVO. The additional funding from other partners allowed to mitigate to some extent the reduction of the number of beneficiaries reached (interview, UDUMA-2, 28 November 2023).
As the interview insights illustrate, the respective priorities and constraints of UDUMA and RVO did not necessarily align for permitting a rapid adaptation to changing circumstances. Yet, at the end of the process, an agreement was reached. Here, the entrepreneurial attitude of the provider may have mattered: “UDUMA made suggestions to adapt the project strategy and the solar pilot was part of it. As the private partner, UDUMA had invested €2 million as their own contribution. UDUMA really wanted to achieve results” (interview, RVO staff, 7 December 2023). Besides, RVO’s approach must be seen in the light of the requirements attached to spending tax-payers’ money for development projects. While tracking the achievement of its political commitments through numbers of people reached, RVO was as well looking for a “systemic change by trying to do new things or [by] doing things differently” (interview, RVO staff, 7 December 2023).
Five years after allocating the initial grant to UDUMA, RVO reflected on wider learnings related to projects supported through its Sustainable Water Fund, putting an emphasis on allowing for more flexibility during project implementation:
[A] more flexible procedure for future programs will allow (more) room for adjustments ... of contracted projects, and for better exploration of interesting new concepts and ideas that otherwise might be lost (too) early (RVO 2022:6). [Therefore,] “program design should allow for flexibility and adaptation of a project, while maintaining the focus on sustainability. ... Learning by doing, and the willingness to improve is at the heart of this, rather than monitoring for accountability only (RVO 2022:18).
UDUMA’s rigid contracts with municipalities allocated operational, commercial, and financial risks to the provider while omitting that flexibility in the financial arrangement may be required to allow for navigating uncertainties. The results suggest that contract renegotiation and effective risk allocation is not only conditional on the agreement of the formal parties to the contract but intimately linked to the behavior of outside actors to the contract and the availability of catalytic resources, permitting contractual changes.
How can renegotiation address incomplete rural drinking water service contracts?
Although local water users do not have a direct contract with UDUMA (Fig. 2), they are crucial for the sustainability of the model as they provide the necessary revenue. Because contractual performance essentially depends on the motivation of the parties involved (North 1990), service providers have an incentive to deploy a delivery approach aligned with the priorities of rural water users to make progress toward expected revenue goals.
Table 2 provides an overview of the service attributes defined in UDUMA’s contract and summarizes the observed results related to the service adaptations. Water quantity relates to the guaranteed minimum supply of volume of water per day and is linked to the infrastructure’s production capacity and borehole yield. Affordability focuses on the tariff design, mainly the tariff structure and level that are defined in a contract in accordance with prevalent tariffing policies. Water quality encompasses actions dedicated to ensuring drinking water is free of fecal and priority chemical contamination and may include measures such as chlorination or regular testing. Reliability defines the maximum time allowed to repair breakdowns. Finally, proximity specifies the distance between the point of source and the household that is related to the source type.
The introduction of the solar kiosks augmented the supply capacity of the waterpoint (water quantity) and reduced the physical effort for pumping as well as the time costs associated with fetching water. In addition to the infrastructure upgrades, the tariff structure at remaining hand pumps was changed, by switching from a volumetric tariff to a monthly flat fee for collecting user payments. The change of the tariff structure complies with Mali’s tariff policy for rural water supply, officially recognizing two payment modalities at hand pumps: direct volume-based payments or regular flat fee contributions (DNH 2007).
For the 10 pilot sites, UDUMA reports that water use remained relatively similar after a hand pump was upgraded to a solar kiosk. Yet, the solar kiosks generated higher revenues compared to handpumps as “there is no reluctance to paying for this service” (UDUMA 2021:35, unpublished report). Regarding the change in payment modalities, field reports from UDUMA indicate that monthly revenues increased and that flat fees appeared to stimulate water use at handpumps (UDUMA 2022, unpublished report). In the following, we contextualize these observed changes by drawing on evidence from interviews conducted with water users in Mali.
Qualitative evidence from the pilot solar kiosks illustrates that users do more readily agree to pay volumetric tariffs at solar kiosks that are professionally managed:
We accept to pay for the tap. But, paying for pumping - that did not work for us! (Female user, Village 8)
The water is fresh, and the service at the solar kiosk is good. I agree to pay per bucket, that works. Before with the hand pump, I came here, too. But the price bothered me. Pumping was really tiring! (Female user, Village 2)
With the solar kiosk, it is really easy. You pay, you get the water, and you leave after only one minute or so. But with the hand pump, you had to work hard - and this for the same price! (Male user, Village 3)
Paying by volume for pumping, this did not work for us. But we accept to pay as we fetch at the solar kiosk. Opening the tap is good - if water is coming when needed. The UDUMA system is reliable, and the water is of good quality. So, I am happy to pay for it. (Female user, Village 9)
Although these results suggest that adapting services to user preferences can unlock payments and increase revenue, seasonal fluctuations in water demand do affect volume-based revenues. For example, even if a solar kiosk is reliably managed, users may decide not to use the guaranteed service but prefer an alternative source for multiple reasons. Insights from user interviews illustrate, for instance, how environmental factors, economic constraints, or specific preferences do influence user behaviors and their source choice, highlighting the challenges of non-exclusive service settings:
In the hot season, I fetch about 10 buckets per day at the solar kiosk. In the rainy season, I use less - maybe five buckets. There is the rainwater, and water is abundant in our wells. (Female user, Village 2)
People are tired of walking - even to the solar kiosk. We want good quality water in proximity, and we would pay our monthly bills. But the solar kiosk does not offer this - I have three wells around me, they are all close by, always available, treated with chlorine bleach, and free of charge. (Male user, Village 5)
Normally I use the UDUMA kiosk. This is closer to my home. But today, I don’t have money, so I go to the Health Centre to get water. (Female user, Village 4)
Today, I collected six 20L-buckets from a traditional well. It is much closer to my house and free of charge. The quality is ok - it is treated with chlorine bleach. (Female user, Village 5)
These insights emphasize that while revising contracts to provide higher service levels by design can lead to improved financial performance, such service adaptations remain a partial response to complex user behaviors. In particular, even if larger quantities of water can be supplied, it is not certain that this level of supply will effectively be demanded by users. As qualitative evidence from Mali suggests, dynamic and contextual water demand is a defining characteristic of rural water supply and a challenge for designing exclusive contracts given the prevalence of alternatives.
The change of the payment modalities at the remaining hand pumps allowed to increase the enforceability of the contract. Under the flat fee approach, the user community self-organizes to collect the required fee and pays UDUMA in advance. As such, the revised contract provides a clear payment enforcement mechanism: if the monthly flat fee is not paid, the UDUMA service is not activated, and the pump is locked by a service area manager until a payment is made (UDUMA 2021, unpublished report). This mechanism mitigates the payment enforcement challenge encountered under the volumetric modality, and simultaneously incentivizes users to make monthly payments against unlimited water use and guaranteed repairs.
However, the strict application of this enforcement mechanism can result in adverse outcomes. When the monthly flat fee is not paid, the pump is closed in the respective month. As a consequence, users are more likely to shift to unimproved water sources, as the following user account illustrates: “Before, I used the hand pump. Now, it is closed - and I rely on the traditional well. I barely use other sources” (Female user, Village 4). In addition to the foregone socioeconomic and health benefits associated with accessing an improved drinking water source (Prüss-Ustün et al. 2019), the provider receives no revenue.
UDUMA may seek to further adapt its services. For instance, the provider could increase its efforts regarding water quality, service reliability, or develop standpipes and household connections to get water closer to the users’ households (Table 2). Any of these interventions would require additional investments (Hutton and Varughese 2016). While it is an open question whether such service adaptations would generate additional revenues, it is, however, unlikely that any of these strategies would overcome the structural barrier of uncertain user demand in the short term.
DISCUSSION
Our application of contract theory to Mali illustrates the potential of and barriers to the professional delivery of contracted rural water services. Three findings emerge from our study with implications for the design and implementation of drinking water service contracts in rural Africa. First, we emphasize that external actors and capital play a crucial role in contract execution and renegotiation. Second, we highlight that the financial architecture of rural water service contracts requires flexibility, particularly when long-term investments are involved, and uncertainties are high. Third, our findings suggest that the ability to revise contracts to adapt services is helpful but remains a partial response to uncertain user demand.
Although contract theory stipulates that “the parties always have the option to renegotiate [the contract] later on” (Hart and Moore 1988:756), this fundamental assumption did not really apply to our case in Mali. Neither did the expressed agreement of the formal parties to the bilateral contract really matter for changing the model. UDUMA’s case emphasizes the crucial role external actors and non-repayable capital from a foundation played to permit renegotiation and support continued work. Any negotiation between UDUMA and the municipalities would most likely not have allowed for fundamental change to the outcomes as additional resources were required. Without the philanthropic grant funding, UDUMA would have had few options to continue their operations.
This insight may be of relevance for further theory development. Following Ågerfalk (2014), we expand on the theoretical implications of our empirical findings, which emphasize that renegotiating contract arrangements is not only conditional on the agreement of the original contract parties but also depends on the involvement and attitude of external actors. Although contract theory puts the formal contract parties in the driving seat of renegotiation, we highlight that the life of a contract must be understood in its wider context of implementation. Therefore, additional qualitative research that complements the more abstract modeling exercises that characterize contract theory is required (Frydlinger and Hart 2024).
Furthermore, our empirical findings pinpoint to an essential limitation of contractual delegation of service delivery functions that is widely established in rural water policies across Africa (Fig. 1). The principle of delegation is based on the implicit assumption that local governments sign the contract on behalf of users. Although individual users are expected to provide the revenue necessary to sustain services, they are not a formal party to UDUMA’s contractual model. Therefore, UDUMA’s model is structurally incomplete. It is likely that other delegation contracts for rural water services suffer from similar shortcomings, chiefly when point sources are concerned. We argue that further research is needed to refine our understanding of the performance of contracts where third parties are crucial for achieving expected outcomes but are not a formal party to the contracting arrangement.
The original financial architecture of the initial contract allocated most financial risks on UDUMA. UDUMA made infrastructure investments by attracting private capital and more traditional donor funding to Mali. Although asset-specific investments require longer time horizons to allow for expected outcomes to be realized (Goldberg and Erickson 1987, Hart and Moore 1988) and tend to be facilitated through more rigid contracts (Hart and Moore 2008, Hart 2017), our case study illustrates the importance of financial flexibility to adapt to uncertainties. We emphasize that the willingness and ability of UDUMA’s holding company to absorb the financial losses was critical for the model to continue. Yet, ODIAL SOLUTIONS was not willing or able to cover further investment risks related to trialing solar kiosks. As the flexibility of the philanthropic grant illustrates, unconditional funding can allow to buffer such risks, particularly in circumstances where investors are facing high uncertainties. Therefore, we suggest that future rural water service contracts involving infrastructure investments may combine a flexible funding component with a certain risk-appetite, such as philanthropic funds, with more traditional donor funding and commercial finance, allowing to navigate a contract impasse.
Finally, we highlight that the design of contracts is necessarily based on assumptions about future behaviors and conditions. Designing contracts applicable to the delivery of water services in rural Africa constitutes a particular challenge because reliable data on water demand are scarce (Therkildsen 1988, Elliott et al. 2019, Hope et al. 2020, Cronk et al. 2024). Yet, conducting accurate demand forecasts remains a fundamental planning challenge even in well-organized sectors in the Global North where reliable data are more readily available (Flyvbjerg et al. 2005). Formal contracts are often based on stable assumptions throughout the year and for multiple years ahead. This “stability assumption” of long-term contracts, similar to other medium- and long-term planning exercises (Therkildsen 1988, Flyvbjerg et al. 2005), likely misses the complexity and uncertainties characterizing rural water. Therefore, allowing for contractual renegotiation can be desirable in the face of changed circumstances or additional experience. As our analysis reveals, contract renegotiation can be a mechanism to respond to gaps between expected and actual performance by acting upon new operational knowledge from implementation. Hence, rural water service contracts require adaptability mechanisms to effectively deal with inherent uncertainty and unpredictability of user demand.
Despite adapting its services, UDUMA remained confronted with volatile and low revenues, emphasizing the uncertainties characterizing rural water demand. Although UDUMA’s initial contracts assumed that no subsidy for operations was needed, the operational reality indicates that in almost all of its sites some form of subsidy is required to meet recurring costs. We argue that rural water contracts are likely to be defined by increasing economic, climate, and social risks that require more pragmatic financial arrangements for supporting service delivery. Governments, service providers, and donors must recognize and adequately plan for these realities. Here, contract theory may help to propose models that combine rigidity in terms of service quality with flexibility in funding arrangements to sustain services. For instance, contracts can provide for flexible compensation mechanisms to cushion revenue shortfalls (Gottardi et al. 2017) or include minimum income guarantees (Guasch et al. 2006, 2008) to achieve desired social, economic, and health impacts associated with safe drinking water.
STUDY LIMITATIONS
Four limitations are recognized in this study. First, the study site lies in one region of Mali, characterized by a unique cultural, social, and political context. Although certain drinking water problems common to rural Africa may be illustrated by using Mali as an example, we do not claim to generalize our findings.
Second, we emphasize that the contractual arrangements underpinning professional service delivery models must be designed in light of the diverse socioeconomic, cultural, and environmental settings in which they operate. Here, selecting UDUMA as one provider offering guaranteed rural water services excludes other possible service delivery approaches from the analysis.
Third, the purposive sampling in rural communities was biased to UDUMA’s upgrades to solar kiosks. We collected data across 8 municipalities, leaving 22 municipalities that also agreed to renegotiate contracts with UDUMA out of the investigation. Because the fieldwork was conducted in collaboration with UDUMA, we were able to get a deep understanding of the model and wider context. However, we also recognize that this may have biased collecting data on the perceptions of the relationship linking the interviewees and UDUMA as the target organization. Therefore, care was taken during analysis to corroborate different sources of empirical data before drawing conclusions.
Fourth, our case-study draws on qualitative data to illustrate how UDUMA’s contractual model evolved over time. Although we provide indicative insights on how users respond to service adaptations and how, in turn, changes in water use and payment behaviors affect revenues, this analysis falls short of estimating the size of these revenue effects. Wagner et al. (2024, 2025) have exploited the longitudinal water use and payment data generated by UDUMA to quantitatively assess the revenue implications associated with service attribute changes.
CONCLUSION
Our study from Mali provides evidence that long-term contracts can attract capacity and finance to the rural water sector. We illustrated that contracts do provide an adaptable framework in which services can evolve and that flexibility in the financial architecture of contracts is necessary to navigate investment risks. Here we highlight the role of philanthropic grants that can act as catalytic and complementary resources to more traditional funding and commercial finance.
Furthermore, the results suggest that although contracts can be revised to adapt services to variable water user demand, professional service delivery models are likely to require operational subsidies to mitigate volatile revenues. Results-based contracts can play an enabling role in the allocation of such subsidies by aligning service outcomes with incentive payments. Permitting for a mix of user payments and performance-based funding may mitigate the risk of service failure due to insufficient local revenue. This is illustrated by an emerging approach that uses a standard contract design in 10 countries in sub-Saharan Africa to allocate flexible subsidies against the provision of rigid results, measured through verifiable key performance indicators related to safe drinking water services (Charles et al. 2023, Uptime 2023).
We emphasize that formal contracts with professional service providers are not a definitive solution to complex water problems. We stress that an enabling policy environment, characterized by a clear legal and institutional environment, with strong regulation and accountability practices and effective subsidy mechanisms is fundamental to support the wider shift toward service delivery. We recognize that these are new practices to the rural water sector that is still focused on more infrastructure-driven approaches, largely ignoring the difficulty of maintaining systems over time. Yet, we argue that well-designed contracts may ultimately allow to crowd in new funding sources and to more effectively allocate responsibilities and risks to deliver drinking water service outcomes that so far have not been achieved in rural Africa.
RESPONSES TO THIS ARTICLE
Responses to this article are invited. If accepted for publication, your response will be hyperlinked to the article. To submit a response, follow this link. To read responses already accepted, follow this link.
AUTHOR CONTRIBUTIONS
Johannes Wagner: Conceptualization, Investigation, Data curation, Formal analysis, Methodology, Project administration, Visualization, Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing. Johanna Koehler: Conceptualization, Methodology, Writing – review & editing. Rob Hope: Supervision, Conceptualization, Funding acquisition, Writing – review & editing.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
Johannes Wagner received funding from the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation programme under the Marie Skłodowska-Curie Innovative Training Network NEWAVE – grant agreement No 861509. This article is an output from the REACH programme, funded by UK Aid from the UK Foreign, Commonwealth and Development Office (FCDO) for the benefit of developing countries (Programme Code 201880). However, the views expressed and information contained in it are not necessarily those of or endorsed by FCDO, which can accept no responsibility for such views or information or for any reliance placed on them.
Use of Artificial Intelligence (AI) and AI-assisted Tools
No Artificial Intelligence (AI) and AI-assisted Tools have been used in the process of writing this paper.
DATA AVAILABILITY
The study involved human subjects and the authors certify that prior to all data collection and analysis, ethical approval was obtained from the Research Ethics Committee of the School of Geography and Environment, University of Oxford (SOGE 1A2020-195 and SOGE 1A2020-210). The data that support the findings of this study are available on request from the corresponding author. None of the data are publicly available because of restrictions (i.e., they contain information that could compromise the privacy of research participants).
LITERATURE CITED
Ågerfalk, P. J. 2014. Insufficient theoretical contribution: a conclusive rationale for rejection? European Journal of Information Systems 23(6):593-599. https://doi.org/10.1057/ejis.2014.35
Athias, L., and S. Saussier. 2018. Are public private partnerships that rigid? And why? Evidence from price provisions in French toll road concession contracts. Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice 111:174-186. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.tra.2018.02.011
Awortwi, N. 2012. Contracting out local government services to private agents: an analysis of contract design and service delivery performance in Ghana. International Journal of Public Administration 35(13):886-900. https://doi.org/10.1080/01900692.2012.686033
Beuve, J., and S. Saussier. 2021. Renegotiations and renewals of public contracts. Review of Industrial Organization 59(3):461-482. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-021-09819-w
Briscoe, J., M. Chakraborty, and S. Ahmed. 1981. How Bengali villagers choose sources of domestic water. Water Supply & Management(5):165-181.
Carter, R. C., E. Harvey, and V. Casey. 2010. User financing of rural handpump water services. In IRC Symposium 2010 Pumps, pipes and promises: costs, finances and accountability for sustainable WASH Services. IRC, The Hague, The Netherlands. https://www.ircwash.org/sites/default/files/Carter-2010-User.pdf
Charles, K., S. Nowicki, A. Armstrong, R. Hope, D. McNicholl, and K. Nilsson. 2023. Results-based funding for safe drinking water services: How a standard contract design with payment for results can accelerate safe drinking water services at scale. University of Oxford and Uptime Global, Oxford, UK.
Cronk, R., J. W. Tracy, and J. Bartram. 2024. The influence of seasonality and multiple water source use on household water service levels. Cleaner Water 1:100012. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.clwat.2024.100012
Direction Nationale de l’Hydraulique du Mali (DNH). 2007. Stratégie Nationale de Développement de l’Alimentation en Eau Potable au Mali. DNH, Bamako, Mali.
Direction Nationale de l’Hydraulique du Mali (DNH). 2020. Rapport de mission. DNH, Bamako, Mali.
Elliott, M., T. Foster, M. C. MacDonald, A. R. Harris, K. J. Schwab, and W. L. Hadwen. 2019. Addressing how multiple household water sources and uses build water resilience and support sustainable development. npj Clean Water 2(1):6. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41545-019-0031-4
Ercan, S. A., and D. Marsh. 2016. Qualitative methods in political science. Pages 309-322 in H. Keman and J. J. Woldendorp, editors. Handbook of research methods and applications in political science. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK. https://doi.org/10.4337/9781784710828.00030
Fehr, E., O. Hart, and C. Zehnder. 2011. How do informal agreements and renegotiation shape contractual reference points? National Bureau for Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts, USA. https://doi.org/10.3386/w17545
Feilzer, M. 2010. Doing mixed methods research pragmatically: implications for the rediscovery of pragmatism as a research paradigm. Journal of Mixed Methods Research 4(1):6-16. https://doi.org/10.1177/1558689809349691
Fetterman, D. M. 2010. Ethnography: step-by-step. SAGE, Thousand Oaks, California, USA. https://doi.org/10.4135/9781071909874
Flyvbjerg, B. 2006. Five misunderstandings about case-study research. Qualitative Inquiry 12(2):219-245. https://doi.org/10.1177/1077800405284363
Flyvbjerg, B. 2011. Case study. Pages 301-316 in N. K. Denzin and Y. S. Lincoln, editors. The SAGE handbook of qualitative research. Fourth edition. SAGE, Rochester, Thousand Oaks, California, USA.
Flyvbjerg, B., M. K. Skamris Holm, and S. L. Buhl. 2005. How (in)accurate are demand forecasts in public works projects?: The case of transportation. Journal of the American Planning Association 71(2):131-146. https://doi.org/10.1080/01944360508976688
Foster, T. 2013. Predictors of sustainability for community-managed handpumps in sub-Saharan Africa: evidence from Liberia, Sierra Leone, and Uganda. Environmental Science & Technology 47(21):12037-12046. https://doi.org/10.1021/es402086n
Foster, T. 2016. From cash flows to water flows: an assessment of financial risks to rural water supply sustainability in sub-Saharan Africa. University of Oxford, Oxford, UK.
Foster, T., S. Furey, B. Banks, and J. Willetts. 2020. Functionality of handpump water supplies: a review of data from sub-Saharan Africa and the Asia-Pacific region. International Journal of Water Resources Development 36(5):855-869. https://doi.org/10.1080/07900627.2018.1543117
Foster, T., and R. Hope. 2016. A multi-decadal and social-ecological systems analysis of community waterpoint payment behaviours in rural Kenya. Journal of Rural Studies 47:85-96. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2016.07.026
Foster, T., and R. Hope. 2017. Evaluating waterpoint sustainability and access implications of revenue collection approaches in rural Kenya. Water Resources Research 53(2):1473-1490. https://doi.org/10.1002/2016WR019634
Foster, T., R. Hope, C. Nyaga, J. Koehler, J. Katuva, P. Thomson, and N. Gladstone. 2022. Investing in professionalized maintenance to increase social and economic returns from drinking water infrastructure in rural Kenya. Policy Brief, Sustainable WASH Systems Learning Program and REACH Programme. University of Oxford, Oxford, UK.
Frydlinger, D., and O. Hart. 2024. Overcoming contractual incompleteness: the role of guiding principles. Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 40(3):625–647. https://doi.org/10.1093/jleo/ewac027
Garrick, D. E., J. W. Hall, A. Dobson, R. Damania, R. Q. Grafton, R. Hope, C. Hepburn, R. Bark, F. Boltz, L. De Stefano, E. O’Donnell, N. Matthews, and A. Money. 2017. Valuing water for sustainable development. Science 358(6366):1003-1005. https://doi.org/10.1126/science.aao4942
Garrick, D. E., M. Hanemann, and C. Hepburn. 2020. Rethinking the economics of water: an assessment. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 36(1):1-23. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grz035
Gerlach, E. 2019. Regulating rural water supply services - a comparative review of existing and emerging approaches with a focus on GIZ partner countries. Deutsche Gesellschaft für Internationale Zusammenarbeit (GIZ) GmbH, Bonn, Germany.
Gerring, J. 2004. What is a case study and what is it good for? American Political Science Review 98(2):341-354. https://doi.org/10.1017/S0003055404001182
Gia, L. H., and T. Fugelsnes. 2010. Public-private partnerships for small piped water schemes: a review of progress in seven African countries. Water Sanitation Program, The World Bank, Nairobi, Kenya.
Goldberg, V. P., and J. R. Erickson. 1987. Quantity and price adjustment in long-term contracts: a case study of petroleum coke. Journal of Law and Economics 30(2):369-398. https://doi.org/10.1086/467141
Gottardi, P., J. M. Tallon, and P. Ghirardato. 2017. Flexible contracts. Games and Economic Behavior 103:145-167. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2016.01.013
Gross, E., and O. Elshiewy. 2019. Choice and quantity demand for improved and unimproved public water sources in rural areas: evidence from Benin. Journal of Rural Studies 69:186-194. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jrurstud.2019.02.021
Guasch, J. L., J.-J. Laffont, and S. Straub. 2006. Renegotiation of concession contracts: a theoretical approach. Review of Industrial Organization 29(1-2):55-73. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-006-9109-5
Guasch, J. L., J.-J. Laffont, and S. Straub. 2008. Renegotiation of concession contracts in Latin America. International Journal of Industrial Organization 26(2):421-442. https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijindorg.2007.05.003
Hart, O. 2003. Incomplete contracts and public ownership: remarks, and an application to public-private partnerships. Economic Journal 113(486):C69-C76. https://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0297.00119
Hart, O. 2017. Incomplete contracts and control. American Economic Review 107(7):1731-1752. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.107.7.1731
Hart, O., and J. Moore. 1988. Incomplete contracts and renegotiation. Econometrica 56(4):755-785. https://doi.org/10.2307/1912698
Hart, O., and J. Moore. 2008. Contracts as reference points. Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(1):1-48. https://doi.org/10.1162/qjec.2008.123.1.1
Herbst, J. I. 2015. States and power in Africa: comparative lessons in authority and control. Princeton University Press, Princeton, New Jersey, USA. https://doi.org/10.1515/9781400852321
Hope, R., T. Foster, J. Koehler, and P. Thomson. 2019. Rural water policy in Africa and Asia. Pages 159-179 in S. J. Dadson, D. E. Garrick, E. C. Penning-Rowsell, J. W. Hall, R. Hope, and J. Hughes, editors. Water science policy and management: a global challenge. John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, UK. https://doi.org/10.1002/9781119520627.ch9
Hope, R., and M. Rouse. 2013. Risks and responses to universal drinking water security. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society A: Mathematical, Physical and Engineering Sciences 371(2002):20120417. https://doi.org/10.1098/rsta.2012.0417
Hope, R., P. Thomson, J. Koehler, and T. Foster. 2020. Rethinking the economics of rural water in Africa. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 36(1):171-190. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxrep/grz036
Hoque, S. F. 2023. Socio-spatial and seasonal dynamics of small, private water service providers in Khulna district, Bangladesh. International Journal of Water Resources Development 39(1):89-112. https://doi.org/10.1080/07900627.2021.1951179
Hoque, S. F., and R. Hope. 2018. The water diary method - proof-of-concept and policy implications for monitoring water use behaviour in rural Kenya. Water Policy 20(4):725-743. https://doi.org/10.2166/wp.2018.179
Huitema, D., E. Mostert, W. Egas, S. Moellenkamp, C. Pahl-Wostl, and R. Yalcin. 2009. Adaptive water governance: assessing the institutional prescriptions of adaptive (co-)management from a governance perspective and defining a research agenda. Ecology and Society 14(1):26. https://doi.org/10.5751/ES-02827-140126
Hutton, G., and M. Varughese. 2016. The costs of meeting the 2030 Sustainable Development Goal Targets on Drinking Water, Sanitation, and Hygiene. World Bank, Washington, D.C., USA. https://doi.org/10.1596/K8543
Hydrophil. 2013. Professionalized rural service areas: a strategy for improving rural water supplies. Volume 1. Strategy overview. Water and Sanitation Program (WSP) and the African Development Bank. The World Bank, Washington, D.C., USA.
Janssens, J. G. 2011. The Affermage-Lease Contract in water supply and sanitation - incentive structures and new developments. The World Bank, Washington, D.C., USA.
Johnson, R. B., A. J. Onwuegbuzie, and L. A. Turner. 2007. Toward a definition of mixed methods research. Journal of Mixed Methods Research 1(2):112-133. https://doi.org/10.1177/1558689806298224
Jones, S. 2013. Sharing the recurrent costs of rural water supply in Mali: the role of WaterAid in promoting sustainable service delivery. Dissertation. University of London, London, UK.
Katuva, J., S. Goodall, P. A. Harvey, R. Hope, and A. Trevett. 2016. FundiFix: exploring a new model for maintenance of rural water supplies. 7th RWSN Forum “Water for Everyone,” Abidjan, Côte d’Ivoire: Rural Water Supply Network, St Gallen, Switzerland. https://rwsnforum7.wordpress.com/wp-content/uploads/2016/11/full_paper_0224_submitter_0276_goodall_susanna1.pdf
Kaushik, V., and C. A. Walsh. 2019. Pragmatism as a research paradigm and its implications for social work research. Social Sciences 8(9):255. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci8090255
Kleemeier, E., and H. Lockwood. 2012. Public-private partnerships for rural water services. IRC International Water and Sanitation Centre, The Hague, Netherlands.
Kleemeier, E., and J. Narkevic. 2010. Private operator models for community water supply - A global review of private operator experiences in rural areas. Field Notes. Water Sanitation Program, The World Bank, Nairobi, Kenya.
Koehler, J., S. Rayner, J. Katuva, P. Thomson, and R. Hope. 2018. A cultural theory of drinking water risks, values and institutional change. Global Environmental Change 50:268-277. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2018.03.006
Koehler, J., P. Thomson, S. Goodall, J. Katuva, and R. Hope. 2021. Institutional pluralism and water user behavior in rural Africa. World Development 140:105231. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2020.105231
Lockwood, H. 2021. Professionalized maintenance for rural water service provision: toward a common language and vision. Sustainable WASH Systems Learning Partnership.
Lockwood, H., P. Chintalapati, C. Cord, and A. Libey. 2021. A roadmap for systems strengthening for professionalized rural water maintenance services. Research Report, USAID, Washington, D.C., USA.
Mannay, D., and M. Morgan. 2015. Doing ethnography or applying a qualitative technique? Reflections from the ‘waiting field.’ Qualitative Research 15(2):166-182. https://doi.org/10.1177/1468794113517391
Martínez-Santos, P. 2017. Determinants for water consumption from improved sources in rural villages of southern Mali. Applied Geography 85:113-125. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.apgeog.2017.06.006
McNicholl, D., R. Hope, A. Money, A. Lane, A. Armstrong, M. Dupuis, A. Harvey, C. Nyaga, S. Womble, J. Allen, J. Katuva, T. Barbotte, L. Lambert, M. Staub, P. Thomson, and J. Koehler. 2020. Results-based contracts for rural water services. Working Paper, Uptime consortium. University of Oxford, Oxford, UK. https://static1.squarespace.com/static/5d5fc19961d87c00011689d2/t/5f1759127e30ed322cd5dba0/1595365662058/Results-Based+Contracts+for+Rural+Water+Services.pdf
McNicholl, D., R. Hope, A. Money, A. Lane, A. Armstrong, N. van der Wilk, M. Dupuis, A. Harvey, C. Nyaga, D. Favre, J. Allen, J. Katuva, T. Barbotte, E. Buhungiro, P. Thomson, and J. Koehler. 2019. Performance-based funding for reliable rural water services in Africa. Working Paper, Uptime consortium. University of Oxford, Oxford, UK. https://static1.squarespace.com/static/5d5fc19961d87c00011689d2/t/5f02887c0e31a70a9c5fc990/1594001552517/Performance-based+funding+for+reliable+rural+water+services.pdf
McNicholl, D., R. Hope, A. Money, A. Lane, M. Dupuis, A. Harvey, S. Womble, J. Allen, J. Katuva, T. Barbotte, L. Lambert, M. Staub, P. Thomson, and J. Koehler. 2021. Delivering global rural water services through results-based contracts. Working Paper, Uptime consortium. University of Oxford, Oxford, UK. https://static1.squarespace.com/static/5d5fc19961d87c00011689d2/t/6172f2fe2d33bc646e09e9ed/1634923266414/Delivering+Global+Rural+Water+Services+through+Results-Based+Contracts.pdf
Ménard, C. 2004. The economics of hybrid organizations. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 160(3):345-376. https://doi.org/10.1628/0932456041960605
Merton, R. K., and P. L. Kendall. 1946. The focused interview. American Journal of Sociology 51(6):541-557. https://doi.org/10.1086/219886
Messick, R. E. 2005. What governments can do to facilitate the enforcement of contracts. In Reforming the business environment: from assessing problems to measuring results. Global Conference, Cairo, Egypt. https://www.enterprise-development.org/wp-content/uploads/MessickDoc.pdf
Ministry of Infrastructure of Rwanda. 2016. National water supply policy. Republic of Rwanda, Kigali, Rwanda. https://rura.rw/fileadmin/Documents/Water/Laws/NATIONAL_WATER_SUPPLY_POLICY__DECEMBER_2016.pdf
Ministry of Water Resources Development and Management of Zimbabwe. 2013. National water policy of Zimbabwe. Government of Zimbabwe, Harare, Zimbabwe. https://faolex.fao.org/docs/pdf/zim183244.pdf
Ministry of Water and Sanitation of Burkina Faso. 2018. National strategy for drinking water services in rural areas of Burkina Faso 2020–2030. Government of Burkina Faso, Ouagadougou, Burkina Faso. https://www.pseau.org/outils/ouvrages/dgep_strategie_nationale_de_gestion_du_service_public_de_l_eau_potable_en_milieu_rural_au_burkina_faso_2020_2030_2018.pdf
Narayanasamy, N. 2009. Participatory rural appraisal: principles, methods and application. SAGE, Los Angeles, California, USA. https://doi.org/10.4135/9788132108382
Nauges, C., and D. Whittington. 2010. Estimation of water demand in developing countries: an overview. The World Bank Research Observer 25(2):263-294. https://doi.org/10.1093/wbro/lkp016
Nilsson, K., R. Hope, D. McNicholl, S. Nowicki, and K. Charles. 2021. Global prospects to deliver safe drinking water services for 100 million rural people by 2030. REACH Working Paper, University of Oxford and RWSN, Oxford, UK.
North, D. C. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511808678
Onwuegbuzie, A. J., and N. L. Leech. 2007. Validity and qualitative research: an oxymoron? Quality & Quantity 41(2):233-249. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11135-006-9000-3
Organisation for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD). 2011. Guidelines for performance-based contracts between municipalities and water utilities. Lessons learnt from Eastern Europe, Caucasus and Central Asia. OECD, Paris, France.
Prüss-Ustün, A., J. Wolf, J. Bartram, T. Clasen, O. Cumming, M. C. Freeman, B. Gordon, P. R. Hunter, K. Medlicott, and R. Johnston. 2019. Burden of disease from inadequate water, sanitation and hygiene for selected adverse health outcomes: an updated analysis with a focus on low- and middle-income countries. International Journal of Hygiene and Environmental Health 222(5):765-777. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ijheh.2019.05.004
Ragin, C. C. 1992. Introduction: cases of “What is a case?” Pages 1-17 in C. C. Ragin and H. S. Becker, editors. What Is a Case?: Exploring the Foundations of Social Inquiry. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK.
REACH and RWSN. 2023. Performance and prospects of rural drinking water services in francophone West Africa. Rural Water Supply Network, St. Gallen, Switzerland. https://www.rural-water-supply.net/en/resources/1159-performance-and-prospects-of-rural-drinking-water-services-in-francophone-west-africa
Republic of Kenya. 2016. The Water Act. Republic of Kenya, Nairobi, Kenya. https://faolex.fao.org/docs/pdf/ken160877.pdf
Republique du Mali. 2002. Code de l’Eau - Loi N°02- 006/ DU 31 Janvier 2002. Journal Officiel De La Republique Du Mali, Bamako, Mali.
Rural Water Supply Network (RWSN). 2010. Myths of the rural water supply sector. RWSN Perspective No 4. RWSN, St Gallen, Switzerland.
RVO (The Netherlands Enterprise Agency). 2017. Sustainable O&M Model for manual pumps in Mali - The UDUMA concept. Netherlands Enterprise Agency, The Hague, Netherlands. https://projects.rvo.nl/project/nl-kvk-27378529-fdw16003ml/
RVO (The Netherlands Enterprise Agency). 2022. A decade of RVO management: the sustainable water fund. Netherlands Enterprise Agency, The Hague, Netherlands.
Sansom, K. R., R. W. A. Franceys, J. I. Morales-Reyes, and C. Njiru, editors. 2003. Contracting out water and sanitation services: Volume 1: Guidance notes for service and management contracts in developing countries. Water, Engineering and Development Centre, Loughborough University, UK. https://hdl.handle.net/2134/30833
Shongwe, M. I., and S. Dlamini. 2021. A systems approach to investigating non-functionality in rural water schemes: a case study. Sustainable Water Resources Management 7(3):24. https://doi.org/10.1007/s40899-021-00509-9
Silverman, D. 2017. Doing qualitative research. Fifth edition. SAGE, Los Angeles California, USA.
Simone, P., L. Macário, and P. M. Hawkins. 2016. Developing delegated management of small water supply systems: the emergence of private sector operators in Mozambique. Water and Sanitation Program, Washington, D.C., USA.
Skarbek, D. 2020. Qualitative research methods for institutional analysis. Journal of Institutional Economics 16(4):409-422. https://doi.org/10.1017/S174413741900078X
Smith, D. W., S. Atwii Ongom, and J. Davis. 2023. Does professionalizing maintenance unlock demand for more reliable water supply? Experimental evidence from rural Uganda. World Development 161:106094. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2022.106094
Therkildsen, O. 1988. Watering white elephants? Lessons from donor funded planning and implementation of rural water supplies in Tanzania. Scandinavian Institute of African studies, Uppsala, Sweden.
Thompson, J., I. Porras, J. Tumwine, M. Mujwahuzi, M. Katui-Katua, N. Johnstone, and L. Wood. 2001. Drawers of water II: 30 years of change in domestic water use & environmental health in East Africa. International Institute for Environment and Development, London, UK.
Tong, A., P. Sainsbury, and J. Craig. 2007. Consolidated criteria for reporting qualitative research (COREQ): a 32-item checklist for interviews and focus groups. International Journal for Quality in Health Care 19(6):349-357. https://doi.org/10.1093/intqhc/mzm042
United Nations General Assembly (UNGA). 2015. Transforming our world: the 2030 Agenda for Sustainable Development (A/RES/70/1). United Nations, New York, New York, USA.
UNICEF and WHO. 2023. Progress on household drinking water, sanitation and hygiene 2000-2022: special focus on gender. UNICEF and WHO, New York, New York, USA.
Uptime. 2023. Results-based funding to secure drinking water for over 4 million rural people - Prospectus. Uptime Global, Oxford, UK. https://static1.squarespace.com/static/5d5fc19961d87c00011689d2/t/640f4075eee8c46a6610d7cd/1678721201951/Uptime-prospectus.pdf
van den Broek, M., and J. Brown. 2015. Blueprint for breakdown? Community based management of rural groundwater in Uganda. Geoforum 67:51-63. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2015.10.009
van der Wilk, N. 2019. Conditions for private sector involvement and financing in the rural water sector. IRC, The Hague, Netherlands.
Van Houtven, G. L., S. K. Pattanayak, F. Usmani, and J.-C. Yang. 2017. What are households willing to pay for improved water access? Results from a meta-analysis. Ecological Economics 136:126-135. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2017.01.023
Wagner, J., J. Koehler, M. Dupuis, and R. Hope. 2024. Is volumetric pricing for drinking water an effective revenue strategy in rural Mali? npj Clean Water 7(1):57. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41545-024-00341-6
Wagner, J., S. Merner, S. Innocenti, A. Geling, and R. Hope. 2025. Can solar water kiosks generate sustainable revenue streams for rural water services? World Development 185:106787. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2024.106787
Water and Sanitation Program (WSP). 2014. Water PPPs in Africa. World Bank, Washington, D.C., USA.
Whaley, L., D. J. MacAllister, H. Bonsor, E. Mwathunga, S. Banda, F. Katusiime, Y. Tadesse, F. Cleaver, and A. M. MacDonald. 2019. Evidence, ideology, and the policy of community management in Africa. Environmental Research Letters 14:085013. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/ab35be
White, G. F., D. J. Bradley, and A. U. White. 1972. Drawers of water: domestic water use in East Africa. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, Illinois, USA.
WHO, UNICEF, and World Bank. 2022. State of the world’s drinking water: an urgent call to action to accelerate progress on ensuring safe drinking water for all. WHO, Geneva, Switzerland.
Williamson, O. E. 1995. The institutions and governance of economic development and reform. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual Conference on Development Economics. World Bank, Washington, D.C., USA. http://documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/333731468739202982/The-institutions-and-governance-of-economic-development-and-reform
Williamson, O. E. 2002. The theory of the firm as governance structure: from choice to contract. Journal of Economic Perspectives 16(3):171-195. https://doi.org/10.1257/089533002760278776
Witzel, A. 1985. Das problemzentrierte Interview. Pages 227-255 in G. Jüttemann, editor. Qualitative Forschung in der Psychologie: Grundfragen, Verfahrensweisen, Anwendungsfelder. Beltz, Weinheim, Germany.
Yin, R. K. 2009. Case study research: design and methods. SAGE, Thousand Oaks, California, USA.
Fig. 1

Fig. 1. Examples of delegation and private sector participation in rural water service delivery. Results of a desk review of national water policies, laws, and regulations. Quotations taken from the following sources: National Strategy for Drinking Water Services in Rural Areas (Ministry of Water and Sanitation of Burkina Faso 2018), Water Act of Kenya (Republic of Kenya 2016), Water Act of Mali (Republique du Mali 2002), National Water Supply Policy (Ministry of Infrastructure of Rwanda 2016), National Water Policy (Ministry of Water Resources Development and Management of Zimbabwe 2013). This overview of policy provisions does not draw conclusions about their implementation in practice.

Fig. 2

Fig. 2. Illustration of UDUMA’s contractual model.

Fig. 3

Fig. 3. The evolution of UDUMA’s contractual model.

Table 1
Table 1. Contract types for the delegation of rural water services. Adapted from existing typologies (Sansom et al. 2003, OECD 2011, Hydrophil 2013, WSP 2014, REACH and RWSN 2023).
Type of contract | Management | Lease/Affermage | Concession | ||||||
Obligations of service provider | Provide specific management services | Operate and maintain assets, deliver water services, undertake billing and tariff collection | Finance and construct new infrastructure, operate and maintain assets, deliver services, undertake billing and tariff collection | ||||||
Typical payment mechanism | Fixed fee | Revenue from customers minus lease fees | Revenue from customers minus concession fees | ||||||
Capital investments | Contracting authority | Shared (infrastructure from contracting authority, operating assets from service provider) | Service provider | ||||||
Asset ownership | Contracting authority | Contracting authority | Contracting authority or service provider | ||||||
Risk transferred to provider | Low | Significant | Major | ||||||
Typical duration | 3–5 years | 6–15 years | 15–30 years | ||||||
Table 2
Table 2. UDUMA’s contract model and the implications of service adaptations on contractual performance.
Service attribute | Contractual condition (Contracting clause) | Initial contract design | Initial contract performance | Renegotiation option | Contract performance after renegotiation | Remaining uncertainties | |||
Water quantity | Management of manual pumps (§1&2). | Expected average use of 2 m³ per day per pump. | Actual average use of 500 liters per day per pump. | Done: (higher service level provided through solar kiosks) | Similar water use. | Uncertain demand: impossible to impose which source and how much water to use. | |||
Maximum supply of 8 m³/day/pump (§3) | Payment collection improves. | Additional costs | |||||||
Monthly revenues increase. | |||||||||
Affordability | User payments as revenue base (§1). | 100% collection efficiency for volumetric payments (PAYF). | 40% collection efficiency | Done: (volumetric tariff structure changed to flat fee) | Water use increases. | Uncertainty about long term effect. | |||
Tariff structure: Volumetric (§21) | Payment collection improves. | Possible to change tariff level but unclear demand and revenue implications. | |||||||
Tariff level: 500 FCFA/m³ (Annex 2) | Monthly revenues increase. | ||||||||
Water quality | Water quality (§14 and Annex 2). | Groundwater assumed to be of good quality (UDUMA 2017). | Qualitative data indicate users are satisfied with water quality. | Potential (increase frequency or range of tests, chlorination) | NA | Additional costs. | |||
Annual test of bio-physical and bacterial parameters. | |||||||||
Shock chlorination in case E. Coli. | |||||||||
Reliability | Max. downtime of 72 hours (Annex 2) | Users value fast and guaranteed repairs (van der Wilk 2019). | Qualitative data suggest UDUMA service is appreciated. | Potential (preventive maintenance, < 24h downtime) |
NA | Unclear if higher reliability is priority for users. | |||
Additional costs. | |||||||||
Proximity | Point sources: manual pumps (§1&2). | Users accept manual pumps. | Qualitative data suggest preference for higher service levels. | Potential (develop standpipes or private connections) | NA | Indicative evidence for user demand but uncertainty prevails. | |||
Additional costs. | |||||||||